Under this model, these assets have continuous prices evolving continuously in time and are driven by Brownian motion processes.[1] This model requires an assumption of perfectly divisible assets and a frictionless market (i.e. that no transaction costs occur either for buying or selling). Another assumption is that asset prices have no jumps, that is there are no surprises in the market. This last assumption is removed in jump diffusion models.
Consider a financial market consisting of financial assets, where one of these assets, called a bond or money market, is risk free while the remaining assets, called stocks, are risky.
A share of a bond (money market) has price at time
with , is continuous, adapted, and has finite variation. Because it has finite variation, it can be decomposed into an absolutely continuous part and a singularly continuous part , by Lebesgue's decomposition theorem. Define:
Thus, it can be easily seen that if is absolutely continuous (i.e. ), then the price of the bond evolves like the value of a risk-free savings account with instantaneous interest rate , which is random, time-dependent and measurable.
Stock prices are modeled as being similar to that of bonds, except with a randomly fluctuating component (called its volatility). As a premium for the risk originating from these random fluctuations, the mean rate of return of a stock is higher than that of a bond.
Let be the strictly positive prices per share of the stocks, which are continuous stochastic processes satisfying:
Here, gives the volatility of the -th stock, while is its mean rate of return.
In order for an arbitrage-free pricing scenario, must be as defined above. The solution to this is:
and the discounted stock prices are:
Note that the contribution due to the discontinuities in the bond price does not appear in this equation.
Each stock may have an associated dividend rate process giving the rate of dividend payment per unit price of the stock at time . Accounting for this in the model, gives the yield process :
It turns out that for a self-financed portfolio, the appropriate value of is determined from and therefore sometimes is referred to as the portfolio process. Also, implies borrowing money from the money-market, while implies taking a short position on the stock.
The term in the SDE of is the risk premium process, and it is the compensation received in return for investing in the -th stock.
Consider time intervals , and let be the number of shares of asset , held in a portfolio during time interval at time . To avoid the case of insider trading (i.e. foreknowledge of the future), it is required that is measurable.
Therefore, the incremental gains at each trading interval from such a portfolio is:
and is the total gain over time , while the total value of the portfolio is .
Define , let the time partition go to zero, and substitute for as defined earlier, to get the corresponding SDE for the gains process. Here denotes the dollar amount invested in asset at time , not the number of shares held.
Given a financial market , then a cumulative income process is a semimartingale and represents the income accumulated over time , due to sources other than the investments in the assets of the financial market.
A wealth process is then defined as:
and represents the total wealth of an investor at time . The portfolio is said to be -financed if:
The corresponding SDE for the wealth process, through appropriate substitutions, becomes:
.
Note, that again in this case, the value of can be determined from .
The standard theory of mathematical finance is restricted to viable financial markets, i.e. those in which there are no opportunities for arbitrage. If such opportunities exists, it implies the possibility of making an arbitrarily large risk-free profit.
In a financial market , a self-financed portfolio process is considered to be an arbitrage opportunity if the associated gains process , almost surely and strictly. A market in which no such portfolio exists is said to be viable.
In a viable market , there exists a adapted process such that for almost every :
.
This is called the market price of risk and relates the premium for the -the stock with its volatility .
Conversely, if there exists a D-dimensional process such that it satisfies the above requirement, and:
,
then the market is viable.
Also, a viable market can have only one money-market (bond) and hence only one risk-free rate. Therefore, if the -th stock entails no risk (i.e. ) and pays no dividend (i.e.), then its rate of return is equal to the money market rate (i.e. ) and its price tracks that of the bond (i.e. ).
In case the number of stocks is greater than the dimension , in violation of point (ii), from linear algebra, it can be seen that there are stocks whose volatilities (given by the vector ) are linear combination of the volatilities of other stocks (because the rank of is ). Therefore, the stocks can be replaced by equivalent mutual funds.
The standard martingale measure on for the standard market, is defined as:
Let be a standard financial market, and be an -measurable random variable, such that:
.
,
The market is said to be complete if every such is financeable, i.e. if there is an -financed portfolio process , such that its associated wealth process satisfies
If a particular investment strategy calls for a payment at time , the amount of which is unknown at time , then a conservative strategy would be to set aside an amount in order to cover the payment. However, in a complete market it is possible to set aside less capital (viz. ) and invest it so that at time it has grown to match the size of .
A standard financial market is complete if and only if , and the volatility process is non-singular for almost every , with respect to the Lebesgue measure.
Karatzas, Ioannis; Shreve, Steven E. (1998). Methods of mathematical finance. New York: Springer. ISBN0-387-94839-2.
Korn, Ralf; Korn, Elke (2001). Option pricing and portfolio optimization: modern methods of financial mathematics. Providence, R.I.: American Mathematical Society. ISBN0-8218-2123-7.