Hicksian demand function

(Redirected from Compensated demand curve)

In microeconomics, a consumer's Hicksian demand function or compensated demand function for a good is their quantity demanded as part of the solution to minimizing their expenditure on all goods while delivering a fixed level of utility. Essentially, a Hicksian demand function shows how an economic agent would react to the change in the price of a good, if the agent's income was compensated to guarantee the agent the same utility previous to the change in the price of the good—the agent will remain on the same indifference curve before and after the change in the price of the good. The function is named after John Hicks.

Mathematically,[1]

.

where h(p,u) is the Hicksian demand function, or commodity bundle demanded, at price vector p and utility level . Here p is a vector of prices, and x is a vector of quantities demanded, so the sum of all pixi is total expenditure on all goods. (Note that if there is more than one vector of quantities that minimizes expenditure for the given utility, we have a Hicksian demand correspondence rather than a function.)

Hicksian demand functions are useful for isolating the effect of relative prices on quantities demanded of goods, in contrast to Marshallian demand functions, which combine that with the effect of the real income of the consumer being reduced by a price increase, as explained below.

Relationship to other functions

edit

Hicksian demand functions are often convenient for mathematical manipulation because they do not require income or wealth to be represented. Additionally, the function to be minimized is linear in the  , which gives a simpler optimization problem. However, Marshallian demand functions of the form   that describe demand given prices p and income   are easier to observe directly. The two are related by

 

where   is the expenditure function (the function that gives the minimum wealth required to get to a given utility level), and by

 

where   is the indirect utility function (which gives the utility level of having a given wealth under a fixed price regime). Their derivatives are more fundamentally related by the Slutsky equation.

Whereas Marshallian demand comes from the Utility Maximization Problem, Hicksian Demand comes from the Expenditure Minimization Problem. The two problems are mathematical duals, and hence the Duality Theorem provides a method of proving the relationships described above.

The Hicksian demand function is intimately related to the expenditure function. If the consumer's utility function   is locally nonsatiated and strictly convex, then by Shephard's lemma it is true that  

Hicksian demand and compensated price changes

edit

Marshallian demand curves show the effect of price changes on quantity demanded. As the price of a good rises, ordinarily, the quantity of that good demanded will fall, but not in every case. The price rise has both a substitution effect and an income effect. The substitution effect is the change in quantity demanded due to a price change that alters the slope of the budget constraint but leaves the consumer on the same indifference curve (i.e., at the same level of utility). The substitution effect always is to buy less of that good. The income effect is the change in quantity demanded due to the effect of the price change on the consumer's total buying power. Since for the Marshallian demand function the consumer's nominal income is held constant, when a price rises his real income falls and he is poorer. If the good in question is a normal good and its price rises, the income effect from the fall in purchasing power reinforces the substitution effect. If the good is an inferior good, the income effect will offset in some degree to the substitution effect. If the good is a Giffen good, the income effect is so strong that the Marshallian quantity demanded rises when the price rises.

The Hicksian demand function isolates the substitution effect by supposing the consumer is compensated with exactly enough extra income after the price rise to purchase some bundle on the same indifference curve.[2] If the Hicksian demand function is steeper than the Marshallian demand, the good is a normal good; otherwise, the good is inferior. Hicksian demand always slopes down.

Mathematical properties

edit

If the consumer's utility function   is continuous and represents a locally nonsatiated preference relation, then the Hicksian demand correspondence   satisfies the following properties:

i. Homogeneity of degree zero in p: For all  ,  . This is because the same x that minimizes   also minimizes   subject to the same constraint.[3]

ii. No excess demand: The constraint   holds with strict equality,  . This follows from continuity of the utility function. Informally, they could simply spend less until utility was exactly  .

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ Jonathan Levin; Paul Milgrom. "Consumer Theory" (PDF). p. 12.
  2. ^ Varian, Hal R. "Chapter 8: Slutsky Equation." Essay. In Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus, 1st ed., 155–56. New York, NY: W W Norton, 2014.
  3. ^ Silberberg E. (2008) Hicksian and Marshallian Demands. In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2702-1