The economics of religion concerns both the application of the techniques of economics to the study of religion and the relationship between economic and religious behaviours.[1][2] Contemporary writers on the subject trace it back to Adam Smith (1776).[3]

Empirical work examines the causal influence of religion in microeconomics to explain individual behaviour[4] and in the macroeconomic determinants of economic growth.[5] Religious economics (or theological economics) is a related subject sometimes[quantify] overlapping or conflated with the economics of religion.[6]

History

edit

Adam Smith laid a foundation for economic analysis for religion in The Wealth of Nations (1776), stating that religious organisations are subject to market forces, incentive and competition problems like any other sector of the economy.[7][need quotation to verify][8] Max Weber later identified a relationship between religion and economic behaviour, attributing in 1905 the modern advent of capitalism to the Protestant reformation.[9]

Religion and individual behaviour

edit

Research highlights the importance of religious orthodoxy on moral behaviours and versions of the Golden Rule “Do unto others as you would have others do unto you” are common to most major religions.[10] Others argue it promotes cooperation and trust within culturally defined groups or clubs.[1] Studies compare the complementary effects of religious values such as charity, forgiveness, honesty and tolerance and religious social groups where membership instils favouritism or discrimination towards in or outgroup members.[11]

Believing

edit

The believing channel of religion behaviours concerns costly effort concerned with divine reputation. Azzi and Ehrenberg (1975) propose individuals allocate time and money to secular and religious institutions to maximise utility in this life and the afterlife.[12] The colonisation of religious minds by the morally concerned supernatural or “Big Gods”[13] diffused behaviours derived from moral instruction.

Belonging

edit

The belonging approach to religion considers the social notion of between and within religious groups. Iannaconne (1998) assigns religion as a 'club good' from a rational choice perspective where costly rituals exclude free-riders from in-group benefits. Field experiments also evidence religious people are more trusting and cooperative with fellow religious adherents. Many experimental studies suggest group belonging has a greater influence on behaviour than belief orthodoxy.[14] As Darwin (1874) among others argue, the promotion of cooperative in-group behaviours is not unique to religious networks.[15]

Experimental economics of religion

edit

Experimental methods can be applied to isolate the effect of religion on behaviour patterns and to distinguish between believing versus belonging channels. Experimental methods are useful in the economics of religion to standardise measurement and identify causal effect.[16] Methods include looking at religion in various games – Prisoner's dilemma, public goods game, ultimatum game, dictator game and parametric choice. Generally, as Hoffman's (2011) survey shows, few statistically significant results have been identified which commentators attribute to opposing positive versus negative effects between and within individuals.[17]

Religion and economic growth

edit
 
The average annual income of countries correlates negatively with national levels of religiosity.[18]

Effects of religion on economic outcomes

Studies suggest there is a channel from religious behaviours to macroeconomic outcomes of economic growth, crime rates and institutional development.[19] Scholars hypothesise religion impacts economic outcomes through religious doctrines promoting thrift, work ethic, honesty and trust.[20] These channels were described by Max Weber in his work The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Weber indicates that Protestant teachings were an important force behind the transition to modern day capitalism in Europe.[21] Other studies highlight the effects of religion on human capital formation as the main mechanism behind the dependency. Human capital formation is driven by higher religious importance of literacy [22]

Effects of economic outcomes on religion

Studies indicate a two-way interaction between economic growth and religion. Secularization theory predicts that economic development reduces religious participation.[23] The empirical evidence in favour of this relationship is mixed.[24][25]

Historical aspects

edit

Religion can have long-lasting effects on a society and its economy. For instance, municipalities of Spain with a history of a stronger inquisitorial presence show lower economic performance and educational attainment today.[26] Similarly, Protestantism in Germany has long affected education and thus economic performance. In 1816, school attendance was about 50% in catholic regions while it was about 66% in Protestant regions.[27] Higher literacy rates of Protestants can be observed in the 1870s/1880s in Prussia. It can be caused by the fact, that Martin Luther favoured Christians reading the Bible by themselves [22] Elements of Protestant ethic described by Weber and economic prosperity may have emerged before the Reformation. In case of England, regions that were exposed to Cistercian monasteries experienced a faster productivity growth from the 13th century onwards. The cultural influence was persistent even after the monasteries were dissolved. Modern attitudes towards hard work are positively related with influence of the Cistercians in the region.[28]

Criticisms

edit

The correlation between religion and economic outcomes can be interpreted in two ways: (1) a feature intrinsic to religion which affects growth or (2) a feature correlated to religion but not religion itself which affects growth. Existing cross-country literature is criticised for inability to distinguish between the two explanations, a problem termed endogeneity bias. Controlling for country fixed effects mitigates bias but more recent studies utilise field and natural experiments to identify the causal effect of religion.[29] Robustness of cross-country results to changes in specification of the statistical models is criticised in the literature.[30]

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ a b Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1998). "Introduction to the Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (3): pp.1465–1495.
  2. ^ McCleary, Rachel M. (2011). The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Religion. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199781287.
  3. ^ Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1998). "Introduction to the Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (3): 1465–1495.
     • Anderson, Gary M. (1988). "Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of Nations," Journal of Political Economy, 96(5), pp. 1066–1088.
  4. ^ Stark, Rodney; Finke, Roger (August 2000). Acts of Faith: Explaining the Human Side of Religion. University of California Press. ISBN 9780520222021.
  5. ^ Barro, Robert J.; McCleary, Rachel M. (2003). "Religion and Economic Growth across Countries". American Sociological Review. 68 (5): 760–781. doi:10.2307/1519761. JSTOR 1519761.
  6. ^ For example, the Journal of Markets & Morality of the Acton Institute for the Study of Religion and Liberty and Faith & Economics of the Association of Christian Economists.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, Elgar, v. 2, part II, Economics of Religion, scrollable table of contents, 10 of 41 papers, 1939–2002.
       • Patrick J. Welch and J.J. Mueller, 2001. "The Relationship of Religion to Economics," Review of Social Economy, 59(2). pp. 185–202. Abstract. Archived 2006-09-15 at the Wayback Machine
       • Paul Oslington, 2000. "A Theological Economics," International Journal of Social Economics, 27(1), pp.\ 32–44.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, Historical Relationships, table of contents, pp. v–vi with links via upper right-arrow to Introduction and first 11 of 17 papers, 1939–2002.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 2, part I, Religious Economics and its Critics, scrollable table of contents, 14 papers, 1939–2002.
       • A.M.C. Waterman, 2002. "Economics as Theology: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations," Southern Economic Journal, 68(4), p pp. 907–921. Reprinted in Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, pp. 321336.
       • Thomas Nixon Carver, 1908. "The Economic Basis of the Problem of Evil," Harvard Theological Review, 1(1), pp. 97111.
       • _____, 1912. The Religion Worth Having. Chapter links.
       • Mahmoud A. El-Gamal, 2006. Islamic Finance: Law, Economics, and Practice. Cambridge. Description and chapter titles.
  7. ^ Smith, Adam (1776). The Wealth of Nations. London: Methuen & Co. p. 749.
  8. ^ Compare: Smith, Adam (1776). "Book V: Of the Revenue of the Sovereign or Commonwealth; Chapter 1: Of the Expences of the Sovereign or Commonwealth". An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Vol. 2. London: Whitestone. pp. 406–407. Retrieved 10 October 2020. The revenue of every established church [...] is a branch [...] of the general revenues of the state, which is thus diverted to purpose very different from the defence of the state. The tythe, for example, is a real land-tax [...]. The more of this fund that is given to the church, the less, it is evident, can be spared to the state. [...] all other things being supposed equal, the richer the church, the poorer must necessarily be, either the sovereign on the one hand, or the people on the other [...].
  9. ^ Weber, Max (2012) [1905]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Courier Corporation. ISBN 9780486122373.
  10. ^ Batson, Charles Daniel; Schoenrade, Patricia; Ventis, W. Larry (1993). Religion and the Individual: A Social-Psychological Perspective. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195062083.
  11. ^ Ruffle, Bradley J.; Sosis, Richard (1 June 2006). "Cooperation and the in-group-out-group bias: A field test on Israeli kibbutz members and city residents". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 60 (2): 147–163. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.740.7036. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2004.07.007. ISSN 0167-2681. S2CID 15402779.
  12. ^ Azzi, Corry; Ehrenberg, Ronald (February 1975). "Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance". Journal of Political Economy. 83 (1): 27–56. doi:10.1086/260305. hdl:1813/75631. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 153985044.
  13. ^ Norenzayan, Ara (2013). Big Gods: How Religion Transformed Cooperation and Conflict. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-1400848324.
  14. ^ Hougland, James G.; Wood, James R. (1980). "Control in Organizations and the Commitment of Members". Social Forces. 59 (1): 85–105. doi:10.2307/2577834. JSTOR 2577834.
  15. ^ Becker, Penny Edgell; Dhingra, Pawan H. (2001). "Religious Involvement and Volunteering: Implications for Civil Society". Sociology of Religion. 62 (3): 315–335. doi:10.2307/3712353. JSTOR 3712353.
  16. ^ Hoffmann, Robert (January 2012). "The Experimental Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Surveys. 27 (5): 813–845. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.227.6634. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00716.x. ISSN 0950-0804. S2CID 145765803.
  17. ^ Obadia, Lionel; Wood, Donald C. (2011). Economics of Religion: Anthropological Approaches. Emerald Group Publishing. ISBN 9781780522296.
  18. ^ WIN-Gallup. "Global Index of religion and atheism" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 October 2012. Retrieved 21 October 2012.
  19. ^ Guiso, Luigi; Sapienza, Paola; Zingales, Luigi (1 January 2003). "People's opium? Religion and economic attitudes". Journal of Monetary Economics. 50 (1): 225–282. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.194.9800. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00202-7. ISSN 0304-3932. S2CID 157112771.
  20. ^ Barro, Robert J.; McCleary, Rachel M. (2003). "Religion and Economic Growth across Countries". American Sociological Review. 68 (5): 760–781. doi:10.2307/1519761. JSTOR 1519761.
  21. ^ Weber, M. (2002). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism: and other writings. Penguin.
  22. ^ a b Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. The quarterly journal of economics, 124(2), 531-596.
  23. ^ McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006). Religion and economy. Journal of Economic perspectives, 20(2), 49-72.
  24. ^ Buser, T. (2015). The effect of income on religiousness. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(3), 178-195.
  25. ^ Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2013). Not the opium of the people: Income and secularization in a panel of Prussian counties. American Economic Review, 103(3), 539-544.
  26. ^ Drelichman, Mauricio; Vidal-Robert, Jordi; Voth, Hans-Joachim (2021-08-17). "The long-run effects of religious persecution: Evidence from the Spanish Inquisition". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 118 (33): e2022881118. doi:10.1073/pnas.2022881118. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 8379970. PMID 34389666.
  27. ^ Wößmann, Ludger (2017-10-12). "Sind Protestanten schlauer?". Zeit.de. Archived from the original on 2017-10-15. Retrieved 2021-08-17.
  28. ^ Andersen, T. B., Bentzen, J., Dalgaard, C. J., & Sharp, P. (2017). Pre‐reformation roots of the protestant ethic. The Economic Journal, 127(604), 1756-1793.
  29. ^ Iyer, Sriya (June 2016). "The New Economics of Religion" (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 54 (2): 395–441. doi:10.1257/jel.54.2.395. S2CID 38991072.
  30. ^ Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., & Tan, C. M. (2012). Is God in the details? A reexamination of the role of religion in economic growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27(7), 1059-1075.
edit