Effects of economic inequality
Effects of income inequality, researchers have found, include higher rates of health and social problems, and lower rates of social goods,[1] a lower population-wide satisfaction and happiness[2][3] and even a lower level of economic growth when human capital is neglected for high-end consumption.[4] For the top 21 industrialised countries, counting each person equally, life expectancy is lower in more unequal countries (r = -.907).[5] A similar relationship exists among US states (r = -.620).[6]
2013 Economics Nobel prize winner Robert J. Shiller said that rising inequality in the United States and elsewhere is the most important problem.[7]
Health
editBritish researchers Richard G. Wilkinson and Kate Pickett have found higher rates of health and social problems (obesity, mental illness, homicides, teenage births, incarceration, child conflict, drug use), and lower rates of social goods (life expectancy by country, educational performance, trust among strangers, women's status, social mobility, even numbers of patents issued) in countries and states with higher inequality. Using statistics from 23 developed countries and the 50 states of the US, they found social and health problems lower in countries like Japan and Finland and states like Utah and New Hampshire with high levels of equality, than in countries (US and UK) and states (Mississippi and New York) with large differences in household income.[8][9]
For most of human history higher material living standards – full stomachs, access to clean water and warmth from fuel – led to better health and longer lives.[1] This pattern of higher incomes and longer lives still holds among poorer countries, where life expectancy increases rapidly as per capita income increases, but in recent decades it has slowed down among middle income countries and plateaued among the richest thirty or so countries in the world.[10] Americans live no longer on average (about 77 years in 2004) than Greeks (78 years) or New Zealanders (78), though the USA has a higher GDP per capita. Life expectancy in Sweden (80 years) and Japan (82) – where income was more equally distributed – was longer.[11][12] It has been suggested that the decline in life expectancy in the United States beginning in the late 2010s is linked to extreme inequality.[13]
In recent years the characteristic that has strongly correlated with health problems in developed countries is income inequality. Creating an index of "Health and Social Problems" from nine factors, authors Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett found health and social problems "more common in countries with bigger income inequalities",[14][15] and more common among states in the US with larger income inequalities.[16] Other studies have confirmed this relationship. The UNICEF index of "child well-being in rich countries", studying 40 indicators in 22 countries, correlates with greater equality but not per capita income.[17] Pickett and Wilkinson argue that inequality and social stratification lead to higher levels of psychosocial stress and status anxiety which can lead to depression, chemical dependency, less community life, parenting problems and stress-related diseases.[18]
In their book, Social Epidemiology, Ichiro Kawachi and S.V. Subramanian found that impoverished individuals simply cannot lead healthy lives as easily as the wealthy. They are unable to secure adequate nutrition for their families, cannot pay utility bills to keep themselves warm during the winter or cold during heat waves, and lack sufficient housing.[19]
Conversely, some researchers have criticised the view that economic inequality causes worse health outcomes, with some studies failing to confirm the relationship or finding that the relationship was more complicated due to issues of determining causality, inadequate data, correlation versus causation or confounding variables (for example, more unequal countries tend to be economically poorer).[20][21][22][23][24]
Education
editThe Impact of Socioeconomic Inequalities
Research conducted by UNESCO's Learning Portal underscores the profound influence of socioeconomic factors on educational access and quality. Children from disadvantaged backgrounds face multiple barriers that hinder their educational progress, including gender disparities, language challenges, and the impacts of crises and conflicts. These factors not only limit immediate access to education but also affect long-term educational attainment and the potential for lifelong learning. For instance, girls in many countries have lower school attendance rates than boys, influenced by factors such as safety concerns, early marriage practices, and household responsibilities. Similarly, linguistic barriers pose significant challenges for children whose home language differs from the language of instruction, often leading to higher dropout rates and academic underperformance.[25]
Geographic Disparities and the ZIP Code Phenomenon
The Harvard Gazette highlights the "almost ironclad link between a child's ZIP code and her chances of success," illustrating how geographic location can mirror achievement levels and perpetuate inequality. In urban areas, particularly, the disparity between schools in affluent neighborhoods versus those in economically disadvantaged areas showcases a stark divide in educational quality and opportunities. This geographical inequality reflects broader societal inequities and underscores the necessity for concerted efforts to address the opportunity gap within the education system.[26]
Towards Inclusive and Equitable Education
Addressing various challenges posed by economic inequality requires a comprehensive approach that encompasses inclusive education policies, pro-poor education strategies, and targeted interventions. UNESCO advocates for education policies that are inclusive and equitable, emphasizing the need for fair funding, special assistance for low-performing schools, and school-community partnerships.[25]
Pro-poor policies, such as cash transfers to encourage attendance and investments in public education that benefit the most disadvantaged, are critical for reducing inequality. Additionally, targeted support for groups facing specific discrimination—such as policies supporting early childhood education, language/bilingual education, and ICT initiatives—can significantly improve educational outcomes for marginalized communities.[25]
Social cohesion
editResearch has shown an inverse link between income inequality and social cohesion. In more equal societies, people are much more likely to trust each other, measures of social capital (the benefits of goodwill, fellowship, mutual sympathy and social connectedness among groups who make up a social units) suggest greater community involvement, and homicide rates are consistently lower.[27]
Comparing results from the question "would others take advantage of you if they got the chance?" in U.S General Social Survey and statistics on income inequality, Eric Uslaner and Mitchell Brown found there is a high correlation between the amount of trust in society and the amount of income equality.[28] A 2008 article by Andersen and Fetner also found a strong relationship between economic inequality within and across countries and tolerance for 35 democracies.
In two studies Robert Putnam established links between social capital and economic inequality. His most important studies[29][30] established these links in both the United States and in Italy. His explanation for this relationship is that
Community and equality are mutually reinforcing... Social capital and economic inequality moved in tandem through most of the twentieth century. In terms of the distribution of wealth and income, America in the 1950s and 1960s was more egalitarian than it had been in more than a century... [T]hose same decades were also the high point of social connectedness and civic engagement. Record highs in equality and social capital coincided. Conversely, the last third of the twentieth century was a time of growing inequality and eroding social capital... The timing of the two trends is striking: somewhere around 1965–70 America reversed course and started becoming both less just economically and less well connected socially and politically.[31]
Albrekt Larsen has advanced this explanation by a comparative study of how trust increased in Denmark and Sweden in the latter part of the 20th century while it decreased in the US and UK. It is argued that inequality levels influence how citizens imagine the trustworthiness of fellow citizens. In this model social trust is not about relations to people you meet (as in Putnam's model) but about people you imagine.[32]
The economist Joseph Stiglitz has argued that economic inequality has led to distrust of business and government.[33]
Crime
editCrime rate has also been shown to be correlated with inequality in society. Most studies looking into the relationship have concentrated on homicides – since homicides are almost identically defined across all nations and jurisdictions. Daly et al. 2001 estimated that about half of all variation in homicide rates among U.S. states and Canadian provinces can be accounted for by differences in the amount of inequality in each province or state.[34] Fajnzylber et al. (2002) found a similar relationship worldwide. Among comments in academic literature on the relationship between homicides and inequality are:
- The most consistent finding in cross-national research on homicides has been that of a positive association between income inequality and homicides.[35]
- Economic inequality is positively and significantly related to rates of homicide despite an extensive list of conceptually relevant controls. The fact that this relationship is found with the most recent data and using a different measure of economic inequality from previous research, suggests that the finding is very robust.[36]
A 2016 study, controlling for different factors than previous studies, challenges the aforementioned findings. The study finds "little evidence of a significant empirical link between overall inequality and crime", and that "the previously reported positive correlation between violent crime and economic inequality is largely driven by economic segregation across neighborhoods instead of within-neighborhood inequality".[37] A 2020 study found that in Europe, the inequality-crime correlation was present but weak (0.10), explaining less than 3% of the variance in crime[38] with a similar finding occurring for the United States,[39] while another 2019 study argued that the effect of inequality on property crime was nearly zero.[40]
Redistribution and welfare
editFollowing the utilitarian principle of seeking the greatest good for the greatest number – economic inequality is problematic. A house that provides less utility to a millionaire as a summer home than it would to a homeless family of five, is an example of reduced "distributive efficiency" within society, that decreases marginal utility of wealth and thus the sum total of personal utility. An additional dollar spent by a poor person will go to things providing a great deal of utility to that person, such as basic necessities like food, water, and healthcare; while, an additional dollar spent by a much richer person will very likely go to luxury items providing relatively less utility to that person. Thus, the marginal utility of wealth per person ("the additional dollar") decreases as a person becomes richer. From this standpoint, for any given amount of wealth in society, a society with more equality will have higher aggregate utility. Some studies[2][3] have found evidence for this theory, noting that in societies where inequality is lower, population-wide satisfaction and happiness tend to be higher.
Philosopher David Schmidtz argues that maximizing the sum of individual utilities will harm incentives to produce.
A society that takes Joe Rich's second unit [of corn] is taking that unit away from someone who . . . has nothing better to do than plant it and giving it to someone who . . . does have something better to do with it. That sounds good, but in the process, the society takes seed corn out of production and diverts it to food, thereby cannibalizing itself.[41]
However, in addition to the diminishing marginal utility of unequal distribution, Pigou and others point out that a "keeping up with the Joneses" effect among the well off may lead to greater inequality and use of resources for no greater return in utility.
a larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken by itself suggests.[42]
When the goal is to own the biggest yacht – rather than a boat with certain features – there is no greater benefit from owning 100 metre long boat than a 20 m one as long as it is bigger than your rival.
Economist Robert H. Frank compare the situation to that of male elks who use their antlers to spar with other males for mating rights.
The pressure to have bigger ones than your rivals leads to an arms race that consumes resources that could have been used more efficiently for other things, such as fighting off disease. As a result, every male ends up with a cumbersome and expensive pair of antlers, ... and "life is more miserable for bull elk as a group."[43]
Firstly, certain costs are difficult to avoid and are shared by everyone, such as the costs of housing, pensions, education and health care. If the state does not provide these services, then for those on lower incomes, the costs must be borrowed and often those on lower incomes are those who are worse equipped to manage their finances. Secondly, aspirational consumption describes the process of middle income earners aspiring to achieve the standards of living enjoyed by their wealthier counterparts and one method of achieving this aspiration is by taking on debt. The result leads to even greater inequality and potential economic instability.[44]
Poverty
editOxfam asserts that worsening inequality is impeding the fight against global poverty. A 2013 report from the group stated that the $240 billion added to the fortunes of the world's richest billionaires in 2012 was enough to end extreme poverty four times over. Oxfam Executive Director Jeremy Hobbs said that "We can no longer pretend that the creation of wealth for a few will inevitably benefit the many – too often the reverse is true."[45][46][47] The 2018 Oxfam report said that the income of the world's billionaires in 2017, $762 billion, was enough to end extreme global poverty four times over.[48]
Jared Bernstein and Elise Gould of the Economic Policy Institute suggest that poverty in the United States could have been significantly mitigated if inequality had not increased over the last few decades.[49][50]
Housing
editIn many poor and developing countries, much land and housing is held outside the formal or legal property ownership registration system. Much unregistered property is held in informal form through various associations and other arrangements. Reasons for extra-legal ownership include excessive bureaucratic red tape in buying property and building; in some countries it can take over 200 steps and up to 14 years to build on government land. Other causes of extra-legal property are failures to notarize transaction documents or having documents notarized but failing to have them recorded with the official agency.[51]
A number of researchers (David Rodda,[52] Jacob Vigdor,[53] and Janna Matlack), argue that a shortage of affordable housing – at least in the US – is caused in part by income inequality.[54] David Rodda[52][55] noted that from 1984 and 1991, the number of quality rental units decreased as the demand for higher quality housing increased (Rhoda 1994:148).[52]
Aggregate demand, consumption and debt
editConservative researchers have argued that income inequality is not significant because consumption, rather than income should be the measure of inequality, and inequality of consumption is less extreme than inequality of income in the US. According to Johnson, Smeeding, and Tory, consumption inequality was actually lower in 2001 than it was in 1986.[56][57] The debate is summarized in "The Hidden Prosperity of the Poor" by journalist Thomas B. Edsall.[58] Other studies have not found consumption inequality less dramatic than household income inequality,[59][60] and the CBO's study found consumption data not "adequately" capturing "consumption by high-income households" as it does their income, though it did agree that household consumption numbers show more equal distribution than household income.[61]
Others dispute the importance of consumption over income, pointing out that if middle and lower income are consuming more than they earn it is because they are saving less or going deeper into debt.[62] Income inequality has been the driving factor in the growing household debt,[59][63] as high earners bid up the price of real estate and middle income earners go deeper into debt trying to maintain what once was a middle class lifestyle.[64]
Central Banking economist Raghuram Rajan argues that "systematic economic inequalities, within the United States and around the world, have created deep financial 'fault lines' that have made [financial] crises more likely to happen than in the past" – the Financial crisis of 2007–08 being the most recent example.[65] To compensate for stagnating and declining purchasing power, political pressure has developed to extend easier credit to the lower and middle income earners – particularly to buy homes – and easier credit in general to keep unemployment rates low. This has given the American economy a tendency to go "from bubble to bubble" fueled by unsustainable monetary stimulation.[66]
Monopolization of labor, consolidation, and competition
editGreater income inequality can lead to monopolization of the labor force, resulting in fewer employers requiring fewer workers .[67] Remaining employers can consolidate and take advantage of the relative lack of competition, leading to less consumer choice, market abuses, and relatively higher real prices.[68][67]
Economic incentives
editSome economists believe that one of the main reasons that inequality might induce economic incentive is because material well-being and conspicuous consumption relate to status. In this view, high stratification of income (high inequality) creates high amounts of social stratification, leading to greater competition for status.
One of the first writers to note this relationship, Adam Smith, recognized "regard" as one of the major driving forces behind economic activity. From The Theory of Moral Sentiments in 1759:
[W]hat is the end of avarice and ambition, of the pursuit of wealth, of power, and pre-eminence? Is it to supply the necessities of nature? The wages of the meanest labourer can supply them... [W]hy should those who have been educated in the higher ranks of life, regard it as worse than death, to be reduced to live, even without labour, upon the same simple fare with him, to dwell under the same lowly roof, and to be clothed in the same humble attire? From whence, then, arises that emulation which runs through all the different ranks of men, and what are the advantages which we propose by that great purpose of human life which we call bettering our condition? To be observed, to be attended to, to be taken notice of with sympathy, complacency, and approbation, are all the advantages which we can propose to derive from it. It is the vanity, not the ease, or the pleasure, which interests us.[69]
Modern sociologists and economists such as Juliet Schor and Robert H. Frank have studied the extent to which economic activity is fueled by the ability of consumption to represent social status. Schor, in The Overspent American, argues that the increasing inequality during the 1980s and 1990s strongly accounts for increasing aspirations of income, increased consumption, decreased savings, and increased debt.
In the book Luxury Fever, Robert H. Frank argues that satisfaction with levels of income is much more strongly affected by how someone's income compares with others than its absolute level. Frank gives the example of instructions to a yacht architect by a customer – shipping magnate Stavros Niarchos – to make Niarchos' new yacht 50 feet longer than that of rival magnate Aristotle Onassis. Niarchos did not specify or reportedly even know the exact length of Onassis's yacht.[70][71]
Economic growth
editTheories
editThe prevailing views about the role of inequality in the growth process has radically shifted in the past century.[72]
The classical perspective, as expressed by Adam Smith, and others, suggests that inequality fosters the growth process.[73][74] Specifically, since the aggregate saving increases with inequality due to higher propensity to save among the wealthy, the classical viewpoint suggests that inequality stimulates capital accumulation and therefore economic growth.[75]
The Neoclassical perspective that is based on representative agent approach denies the role of inequality in the growth process. It suggests that the while the growth process may affect inequality, income distribution has no impact on the growth process.
The modern perspective which has emerged in the late 1980s suggests, in contrast, that income distribution has a significant impact on the growth process. The modern perspective, originated by Galor and Zeira,[76][77] highlights the important role of heterogeneity in the determination of aggregate economic activity, and economic growth. In particular, Galor and Zeira argue that since credit markets are imperfect, inequality has an enduring impact on human capital formation, the level of income per capita, and the growth process.[78] In contrast to the classical paradigm, which underlined the positive implications of inequality for capital formation and economic growth, Galor and Zeira argue that inequality has an adverse effect on human capital formation and the development process, in all but the very poor economies.
Later theoretical developments have reinforced the view that inequality has an adverse effect on the growth process. Specifically, Alesina and Rodrik and Persson and Tabellini advance a political economy mechanism and argue that inequality has a negative impact on economic development since it creates a pressure for distortionary redistributive policies that have an adverse effect on investment and economic growth.[79][80]
A unified theory of inequality and growth that captures that changing role of inequality in the growth process offers a reconciliation between the conflicting predictions of classical viewpoint that maintained that inequality is beneficial for growth and the modern viewpoint that suggests that in the presence of credit market imperfections, inequality predominantly results in under investment in human capital and lower economic growth. This unified theory of inequality and growth, developed by Oded Galor and Omer Moav,[81] suggests that the effect of inequality on the growth process has been reversed as human capital has replaced physical capital as the main engine of economic growth. In the initial phases of industrialization, when physical capital accumulation was the dominating source of economic growth, inequality boosted the development process by directing resources toward individuals with higher propensity to save. However, in later phases, as human capital became the main engine of economic growth, more equal distribution of income, in the presence of credit constraints, stimulated investment in human capital and economic growth.
Evidence
editThe reduced form empirical relationship between inequality and growth was studies by Alberto Alesina and Dani Rodrik,[79] and Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini.[80] They find that inequality is negatively associated with economic growth in a cross-country analysis.
A 1999 review in the Journal of Economic Literature states high inequality lowers growth, perhaps because it increases social and political instability.[82] The article also says:
Somewhat unusually for the growth literature, studies have tended to concur in finding a negative effect of high inequality on subsequent growth. The evidence has not been accepted by all: some writers point out the concentration of richer countries at the lower end of the inequality spectrum, the poor quality of the distribution data, and the lack of robustness to fixed effects specifications. At least, though, it has become extremely difficult to build a case that inequality is good for growth. This in itself represents a considerable advance. Given the indications that inequality is harmful for growth, attention has moved on to the likely mechanisms.... the literature seems to be moving ... towards an examination of the effects of inequality on fertility rates, investment in education, and political stability.[82]
A 1992 World Bank report published in the Journal of Development Economics said that
Inequality is negatively, and robustly, correlated with growth. This result is not highly dependent upon assumptions about either the form of the growth regression or the measure of inequality...Although statistically significant, the magnitude of the relationship between inequality and growth is relatively small.[83]
NYU economist William Baumol found that substantial inequality does not stimulate growth because poverty reduces labor force productivity.[84] Economists Dierk Herzer and Sebastian Vollmer found that increased income inequality reduces economic growth, but growth itself increases income inequality.[85]
A 1996 study by Perotti examined the channels through which inequality may affect economic growth. He showed that, in accordance with the credit market imperfection approach, inequality is associated with lower level of human capital formation (education, experience, and apprenticeship) and higher level of fertility, and thereby lower levels of growth. He found that inequality is associated with higher levels of redistributive taxation, which is associated with lower levels of growth from reductions in private savings and investment. Perotti concluded that, "more equal societies have lower fertility rates and higher rates of investment in education. Both are reflected in higher rates of growth. Also, very unequal societies tend to be politically and socially unstable, which is reflected in lower rates of investment and therefore growth."[88]
Robert Barro reexamined the reduced form relationship between inequality on economic growth in a panel of countries.[89] He argues that there is "little overall relation between income inequality and rates of growth and investment." However, his empirical strategy limits its applicability to the understanding of the relationship between inequality and growth for several reasons. First, his regression analysis control for education, fertility, investment, and it therefore excludes, by construction, the important effect of inequality on growth via education, fertility, and investment. His findings simply imply that inequality has no direct effect on growth beyond the important indirect effects through the main channels proposed in the literature. Second his study analyzes the effect of inequality on the average growth rate in the following 10 years. However, existing theories suggest that the effect of inequality will be observed much later, as is the case in human capital formation, for instance. Third, the empirical analysis does not account for biases that are generated by reverse causality and omitted variables.
A study of Swedish counties between 1960 and 2000 found a positive impact of inequality on growth with lead times of five years or less, but no correlation after ten years.[90] Studies of larger data sets have found no correlations for any fixed lead time,[91] and a negative impact on the duration of growth.[86]
Some theories developed in the 1970s established possible avenues through which inequality may have a positive effect on economic development.[86][87] According to a 1955 review, savings by the wealthy, if these increase with inequality, were thought to offset reduced consumer demand.[92]
According to International Monetary Fund economists, inequality in wealth and income is negatively correlated with the duration of economic growth spells (not the rate of growth).[86] High levels of inequality prevent not just economic prosperity, but also the quality of a country's institutions and high levels of education.[93] According to IMF staff economists, "if the income share of the top 20 percent (the rich) increases, then GDP growth actually declines over the medium term, suggesting that the benefits do not trickle down. In contrast, an increase in the income share of the bottom 20 percent (the poor) is associated with higher GDP growth. The poor and the middle class matter the most for growth via a number of interrelated economic, social, and political channels."[94]
However, further work done in 2015 by Sutirtha Bagchi and Jan Svejnar suggests that it is only inequality caused by corruption and cronyism that harms growth. When they control for the fact that some inequality is caused by billionaires using their political connections, then inequality caused by market forces does not seem to have an effect on growth.[95]
Economist Joseph Stiglitz presented evidence in 2009 that both global inequality and inequality within countries prevent growth by limiting aggregate demand.[96] Economist Branko Milanovic, wrote in 2001 that, "The view that income inequality harms growth – or that improved equality can help sustain growth – has become more widely held in recent years. ... The main reason for this shift is the increasing importance of human capital in development. When physical capital mattered most, savings and investments were key. Then it was important to have a large contingent of rich people who could save a greater proportion of their income than the poor and invest it in physical capital. But now that human capital is scarcer than machines, widespread education has become the secret to growth."[4]
Studies on income inequality and growth have sometimes found evidence confirming the Kuznets curve hypothesis, which states that with economic development, inequality first increases, then decreases.[83] Economist Thomas Piketty challenges this notion, claiming that from 1914 to 1945 wars and "violent economic and political shocks" reduced inequality. Moreover, Piketty argues that the "magical" Kuznets curve hypothesis, with its emphasis on the balancing of economic growth in the long run, cannot account for the significant increase in economic inequality throughout the developed world since the 1970s.[97] However, Kristin Forbes found that if country-specific effects were eliminated by using panel estimation, then income inequality does have a significant positive relationship with economic growth. This relationship held across different "samples, variable definitions, and model specifications."[98] Historian Walter Scheidel, who builds on Piketty's thesis that it has been violent shocks that have reduced inequality in The Great Leveler (2017), contends that "the preponderance of the evidence fails to support the idea of a systematic relationship between economic growth and income inequality as first envisioned by Kuznets sixty years ago."[99]
A 2012 study published by Inyong Shin of Asia University found that economic inequality in the developed world has a very different effect on economic growth than in the developing world, saying that "higher inequality can retard growth in the early stage of economic development", but that "higher inequality can encourage growth in a near steady state".[100]
A 2013 report on Nigeria suggests that growth has risen with increased income inequality.[101] Some theories popular from the 1950s to 2011 argued that inequality had a positive effect on economic development.[86][87] However, Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo argue that analyses based on comparing yearly equality figures to yearly growth rates were misleading because it takes several years for effects to manifest as changes to economic growth.[91] IMF economists found a strong association between lower levels of inequality in developing countries and sustained periods of economic growth. Developing countries with high inequality have "succeeded in initiating growth at high rates for a few years" but "longer growth spells are robustly associated with more equality in the income distribution."[87]
An OECD study in 2015, found that internationally "countries where income inequality is decreasing grow faster than those with rising inequality", and noted that "a lack of investment in education by the poor is the main factor behind inequality hurting growth"[102]
A 2016 meta-analysis found that "the effect of inequality on growth is negative and more pronounced in less developed countries than in rich countries", though the average impact on growth was not significant. The study also found that wealth, land and human capital inequality is more pernicious to growth than income inequality.[103]
A 2017 study argued that there were both positive and negative effects of inequality: "When inequality is associated with political instability and social unrest, rent-seeking and distortive policies, lower capacities for investment in human capital, and a stagnant domestic market, it is mostly expected to harm long-run economic performance, as suggested by many authors. Accordingly, improving income distribution is expected to foster long-run economic growth, especially in low-income countries where the levels of inequality are usually very high. However, some degree of inequality can also be good, as has been theoretically argued in the literature and as empirically suggested in this study. A degree of inequality can play a beneficial role for economic growth when that inequality is driven by market forces and related to hard work and growth-enhancing incentives like risk taking, innovation, capital investment, and agglomeration economies. The challenge for policy makers is to control structural inequality, which reduces the country's capacities for economic development, while at the same time keeping in place those positive incentives that are also necessary for growth."[104]
Mechanisms
editThe Galor and Zeira's model predicts that the effect of rising inequality on GDP per capita is negative in relatively rich countries but positive in poor countries.[76][77] These testable predictions have been examined and confirmed empirically in recent studies.[105][106] In particular, Brückner and Lederman test the prediction of the model by in the panel of countries during the period 1970–2010, by considering the impact of the interaction between the level of income inequality and the initial level of GDP per capita. In line with the predictions of the model, they find that at the 25th percentile of initial income in the world sample, a 1 percentage point increase in the Gini coefficient increases income per capita by 2.3%, whereas at the 75th percentile of initial income a 1 percentage point increase in the Gini coefficient decreases income per capita by -5.3%. Moreover, the proposed human capital mechanism that mediate the effect of inequality on growth in the Galor-Zeira model is also confirmed. Increases in income inequality increase human capital in poor countries but reduce it in high and middle-income countries.
This recent support for the predictions of the Galor-Zeira model is in line with earlier findings. Roberto Perotti showed that in accordance with the credit market imperfection approach, developed by Galor and Zeira, inequality is associated with lower level of human capital formation (education, experience, apprenticeship) and higher level of fertility, while lower level of human capital is associated with lower levels of economic growth.[107] Princeton economist Roland Benabou's finds that the growth process of Korea and the Philippines "are broadly consistent with the credit-constrained human-capital accumulation hypothesis."[108] In addition, Andrew Berg and Jonathan Ostry suggest that inequality seems to affect growth through human capital accumulation and fertility channels.[109]
In contrast, Perotti argues that the political economy mechanism is not supported empirically. Inequality is associated with lower redistribution, and lower redistribution (under-investment in education and infrastructure) is associated with lower economic growth.[107]
According to economist Branko Milanovic, while traditionally economists thought inequality was good for growth
The view that income inequality harms growth – or that improved equality can help sustain growth – has become more widely held in recent years. ... The main reason for this shift is the increasing importance of human capital in development. When physical capital mattered most, savings and investments were key. Then it was important to have a large contingent of rich people who could save a greater proportion of their income than the poor and invest it in physical capital. But now that human capital is scarcer than machines, widespread education has become the secret to growth.[4]
"Broadly accessible education" is both difficult to achieve when income distribution is uneven and tends to reduce "income gaps between skilled and unskilled labor."
The sovereign-debt economic problems of the late twenty-oughts do not seem to be correlated to redistribution policies in Europe. With the exception of Ireland, the countries at risk of default in 2011 (Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal) were notable for their high Gini-measured levels of income inequality compared to other European countries. As measured by the Gini index, Greece as of 2008 had more income inequality than the economically healthy Germany.[110]
Equitable growth
editWhile acknowledging the central role economic growth can potentially play in human development, poverty reduction and the achievement of the Millennium Development Goals, it is becoming widely understood among the development community that special efforts must be made to ensure poorer sections of society are able to participate in economic growth.[111][112][113] The effect of economic growth on poverty reduction – the growth elasticity of poverty – can depend on the existing level of inequality.[114][115] For instance, with low inequality a country with a growth rate of 2% per head and 40% of its population living in poverty, can halve poverty in ten years, but a country with high inequality would take nearly 60 years to achieve the same reduction.[116][117] In the words of the Secretary-General of the United Nations Ban Ki-moon: "While economic growth is necessary, it is not sufficient for progress on reducing poverty."[111] Competition policy intending to prevent companies from abusing market power contributes to inclusive growth.[118]
Environment
editMultiple arguments can be made about the relationship between poverty and the environment. In some cases, alleviating poverty can result in detrimental environmental affects or exacerbate degradation; the smaller the economic inequality, the more waste and pollution is created, resulting in many cases, in more environmental degradation. This can be explained by the fact that as the poor people in the society become more wealthy, it increases their yearly carbon emissions. This relation is expressed by the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC).[119]{ In certain cases, with great economic inequality, there is nonetheless not more waste and pollution created as the waste/pollution is cleaned up better afterwards (water treatment, filtering, ... )[120] Also note that the whole of the increase in environmental degradation is the result of the increase of emissions per person being multiplied by a multiplier. If there were fewer people, however, this multiplier would be lower, and thus the amount of environmental degradation would be lower as well. As such, the current high level of population has a large impact on this as well. If (as WWF argued), population levels would start to drop to a sustainable level (1/3 of current levels, so about 2 billion people[121]), human inequality can be addressed/corrected, while still not resulting in an increase of environmental damage.
On the other hand, other sources argue that alleviating poverty will reap positive progressions on the environment, especially with technological advances in energy efficiency. Urbanization, for instance, can "reduce the area in which humans impact the environment, thereby protecting nature elsewhere."[122] Through concentration human societies, urbanized regions can allow for more allocated reserves for wildlife. Moreover, through urbanization, such societies have a higher standard of living that can promote environmental health with better food, technology, education, and more. In more unequal societies, there are stronger drivers for consumerism and stronger belief in free enterprise, and the rich also use a disproportionate amount of resources. Thus, in developed countries, inequality tends to accelerate resource consumption by all classes.[123]
Research also shows that biodiversity loss is higher in countries or in US states with higher income inequality.[124]
Political outcomes
editHigher income inequality led to less of all forms of social, cultural, and civic participation among the less wealthy.[125] When inequality is higher the poor do not shift to less expensive forms of participation.[126]
In 2015, a study by Lahtinen and Wass suggested that low social mobility reduces turnout among lower classes.[127]
According to a 2017 review study in the Annual Review of Political Science by Stanford University political scientists Kenneth Scheve and David Stasavage, "the simple conjectures that democracy produces wealth equality and that wealth inequality leads to democratic failure are not supported by the evidence."[128]
Some, such as Alberto Alesina and Dani Rodrik, argue that economic inequality creates demand for redistribution and the creation of welfare states.[129] A 2014 study questions this relationship, finding that "inequality did not favour the development of social policy between 1880 and 1930. On the contrary, social policy developed more easily in countries that were previously more egalitarian, suggesting that unequal societies were in a sort of inequality trap, where inequality itself was an obstacle to redistribution."[130]
War, terrorism and political instability
editOne study finds a correlation between income inequality and increased levels of political instability.[131] A 2016 study finds that interregional inequality increases terrorism.[132] Another 2016 study finds that inequality between social classes increases the likelihood of coups but not civil wars.[133] A lack of reliable data makes it difficult to study the relationship between inequality and political violence.[134]
A 2014 study published in Ecological Economics said that economic stratification of society into "elites" and "masses" played a central role in the collapse of other advanced civilizations such as the Roman, Han, and Gupta empires.[135] John A. Hobson, Rosa Luxemburg, and Vladimir Lenin argued that World War I was caused by inequality. In his 2016 book Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization, economist Branko Milanović says that there is credence to this argument.[136]
See also
editReferences
edit- ^ a b Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, p. 5.
- ^ a b "Happiness: Has Social Science A Clue?" Richard Layard Archived June 3, 2013, at the Wayback Machine 2003
- ^ a b Blanchard and Oswald 2000, 2003
- ^ a b c More or Less| Branko Milanovic| Finance & Development| September 2011| Vol. 48, No. 3
- ^ De Vogli, R. (2005). "Has the relation between income inequality and life expectancy disappeared? Evidence from Italy and top industrialised countries". Journal of Epidemiology & Community Health. 59 (2): 158–62. doi:10.1136/jech.2004.020651. PMC 1733006. PMID 15650149.
- ^ Kaplan, G. A; Pamuk, E. R; Lynch, J. W; Cohen, R. D; Balfour, J. L (1996). "Inequality in income and mortality in the United States: Analysis of mortality and potential pathways". BMJ. 312 (7037): 999–1003. doi:10.1136/bmj.312.7037.999. PMC 2350835. PMID 8616393.
- ^ Christoffersen, John (October 14, 2013). "Rising inequality 'most important problem,' says Nobel-winning economist". St. Louis Post-Dispatch. Retrieved October 19, 2013.
- ^ "The Spirit Level". equalitytrust.org.uk.
- ^ Pickett, KE; Wilkinson, RG (March 2015). "Income inequality and health: a causal review". Social Science & Medicine. 128: 316–26. doi:10.1016/j.socscimed.2014.12.031. PMID 25577953.
- ^ Sapolsky, Robert (2005). "Sick of Poverty". Scientific American. 293 (6): 92–9. Bibcode:2005SciAm.293f..92S. doi:10.1038/scientificamerican1205-92. PMID 16323696.
- ^ Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, p. 82.
- ^ (At the same time however, there is a strong connection between average income and health within countries. Example: Comparing average death rates in United States zip code areas organized by average income finds the highest income zip codes average a little over 90 deaths per 10,000, the poorest zip codes a little over 50 deaths and a "strikingly" regular gradient of death rates for income in between. source: Figure 1.4, Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, p. 13, Authors: "What is so striking about Figure 1.4 is how regular the health gradient is right across society". Data from: Smith, G D; Neaton, J D; Wentworth, D; Stamler, R; Stamler, J (1996). "Socioeconomic differentials in mortality risk among men screened for the Multiple Risk Factor Intervention Trial: I. White men". American Journal of Public Health. 86 (4): 486–96. doi:10.2105/AJPH.86.4.486. PMC 1380548. PMID 8604778.)
- ^ "Suicides and Drug Overdose Deaths Push Down US Life Expectancy". Voice of America. November 29, 2018. Retrieved January 13, 2019.
William Dietz is with George Washington University in Washington, D.C. He suggested that financial struggles, inequality and divisive politics are all depressing many Americans. "I really do believe that people are increasingly hopeless, and that that leads to drug use, it leads...to suicide," he said.
- ^ Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, pp. 306–9. Figure 2.2 found on p. 20 and this page
- ^ the authors found a Pearson Correlation Coefficient of 0.87 for the index and inequality among 20 developed countries for which data was available. Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, p. 310.
- ^ a coefficient of 0.59 for 40 US states for which data was available (the index for US states did not include a component for mobility in its index). For both populations the statistical significance p-value was >0.01. Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, p. 310.
- ^ compare figures 2.6 and 2.7 in Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level, 2011, pp. 23–4. Data from An overview of child well-being in rich countries Archived 2019-09-03 at the Wayback Machine The United Nations Children's Fund, 2007
- ^ The Spirit Level: how 'ideas wreckers' turned book into political punchbag| Robert Booth| The Guardian| August 13, 2010
- ^ Kawachi, Ichiro. S.V. Subramanian. Social Epidemiology. p. 126.[full citation needed]
- ^ Snowdon, Christopher. The spirit level delusion: fact-checking the left's new theory of everything. Little Dice, 2010.
- ^ Eckersley, Richard. "Beyond inequality: Acknowledging the complexity of social determinants of health." Social Science & Medicine 147 (2015): 121-125.
- ^ Antony, Jürgen, and Torben Klarl. "Estimating the income inequality-health relationship for the United States between 1941 and 2015: Will the relevant frequencies please stand up?." The Journal of the Economics of Ageing 17 (2020): 100275.
- ^ Leigh, Andrew, Christopher Jencks, and Timothy M. Smeeding. "Health and economic inequality." The Oxford handbook of economic inequality (2009): 384-405.
- ^ Kim, Ki‐tae. "Income inequality, welfare regimes and aggregate health: Review of reviews." International Journal of Social Welfare 28, no. 1 (2019): 31-43.
- ^ a b c "Socioeconomic inequalities and learning". IIEP Learning Portal. Unesco Learning Portal.
- ^ "The costs of inequality: Education's the one key that rules them all". The Harvard Gazette. The Harvard News.
- ^ Leenders, Roger (2014), "Social Capital", in Alhajj, Reda; Rokne, Jon (eds.), Encyclopedia of Social Network Analysis and Mining, New York, NY: Springer, pp. 1759–1770, doi:10.1007/978-1-4614-6170-8_92, ISBN 978-1-4614-6170-8, S2CID 35238250
- ^ Inequality Trust and Political Engagement Eric Uslaner and Mitchell Brown, 2002
- ^ Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti, 1993)
- ^ Robert Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community 2000
- ^ Robert Putnam, Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community, 2000, p. 359.
- ^ Albrekt Larsen, Christian (2013). The Rise and Fall of Social Cohesion: The Construction and De-construction of Social Trust in the US, UK, Sweden and Denmark. Oxford: Oxford University Press[page needed]
- ^ Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future. W.W. Norton & Company. ISBN 978-0-393-08869-4.[page needed]
- ^ Income inequality and homicide rates in Canada and The United Archived October 2, 2008, at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Neapolitan, Jerome L (1999). "A comparative analysis of nations with low and high levels of violent crime". Journal of Criminal Justice. 27 (3): 259–74. doi:10.1016/S0047-2352(98)00064-6.
- ^ Lee, Matthew R.; Bankston, William B. (1999). "Political structure, economic inequality, and homicide: A cross-national analysis". Deviant Behavior. 20 (1): 27–55. doi:10.1080/016396299266588.
- ^ Kang, Songman (2015). "Inequality and crime revisited: Effects of local inequality and economic segregation on crime". Journal of Population Economics. 29 (2): 593–626. doi:10.1007/s00148-015-0579-3. S2CID 155852321.
- ^ Kim, Bitna, Chunghyeon Seo, and Young-Oh Hong. "A Systematic Review and Meta-analysis of Income Inequality and Crime in Europe: Do Places Matter?." European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research (2020): 1-24.
- ^ Atems, Bebonchu. "Identifying the Dynamic Effects of Income Inequality on Crime." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics (2020).
- ^ Corvalana, Alejandro, and Matteo Pazzonab. "Does Inequality Really Increase Crime? Theory and Evidence." In Technical Report. 2019.
- ^ The Elements of Justice By David Schmidtz (2006)
- ^ Cecil, Arthur. The Economics of Welfare.
- ^ Whitfield, John (28 September 2011). "Libertarians With Antlers". slate.com. Retrieved 6 November 2012.
- ^ Milo Vandemoortele 2010. Equity: a key to macroeconomic stability Archived 2010-11-23 at the Wayback Machine. London: Overseas Development Institute
- ^ Slater, John (January 19, 2013). "Annual income of richest 100 people enough to end global poverty four times over". Oxfam. Retrieved September 20, 2014.
- ^ Khazan, Olga (January 20, 2013). "Can we fight poverty by ending extreme wealth?". The Washington Post. Retrieved September 20, 2014.
- ^ "Oxfam seeks 'new deal' on inequality from world leaders". BBC News. January 18, 2013. Retrieved September 20, 2014.
- ^ Hagan, Shelly (January 22, 2018). "Billionaires Made So Much Money Last Year They Could End Extreme Poverty Seven Times". Money. Retrieved December 13, 2018.
- ^ Jared Bernstein (January 13, 2014). Poverty and Inequality, in Charts. The New York Times Retrieved September 20, 2014.
- ^ Elise Gould (January 15, 2014). No Matter How We Measure Poverty, the Poverty Rate Would Be Much Lower If Economic Growth Were More Broadly Shared. Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved September 20, 2014.
- ^ De Soto, Hernando (2000). The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. Basic Books. pp. 153–206. ISBN 978-0-465-01615-0.
- ^ a b c David T Rodda (1994). Rich Man, Poor Renter: A Study of the Relationship Between the Income Distribution and Low Cost Rental Housing (Thesis). Harvard University.
- ^ Vigdor, Jacob (2002). "Does Gentrification Harm the Poor?". Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs. 2002: 133–182. doi:10.1353/urb.2002.0012. S2CID 155028628.
- ^ Matlack, Janna L.; Vigdor, Jacob L. (2008). "Do rising tides lift all prices? Income inequality and housing affordability" (PDF). Journal of Housing Economics. 17 (3): 212–24. doi:10.1016/j.jhe.2008.06.004.
- ^ (cited in Matlack Do Rising Tides Lift All Prices? Income Inequality and Housing Affordability, 2006)
- ^ Johnson, Smeeding, Tory, "Economic Inequality" in Monthly Labor review of April 2005, table 3.
- ^ see also "Consumption and the Myths of Inequality", by Kevin Hassett and Aparna Mathur, The Wall Street Journal, October 24, 2012
- ^ a b "Conservative Inequality Denialism," by Timothy Noah The New Republic (October 25, 2012)
- ^ Attanasio, Orazio; Hurst, Erik; Pistaferri, Luigi (2012). "The Evolution of Income, Consumption, and Leisure Inequality in The US, 1980–2010". NBER Working Paper No. 17982. SSRN 2035781.
- ^ Congressional Budget Office: Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007. October 2011. p. 5
- ^ "The United States of Inequality, Entry 10: Why We Can't Ignore Growing Income Inequality," by Timothy Noah, Slate (September 16, 2010)
- ^ The Way Forward Archived July 11, 2012, at archive.today By Daniel Alpert, Westwood Capital; Robert Hockett, Professor of Law, Cornell University; and Nouriel Roubini, Professor of Economics, New York University, New America Foundation, October 10, 2011
- ^ Plumer, Brad. "'Trickle-down consumption': How rising inequality can leave everyone worse off". 27 March 2013. Washington Post. Retrieved March 27, 2013.
- ^ Lo, Andrew W. "Reading About the Financial Crisis: A 21-Book Review" (PDF). 2012. Journal of Economic Literature . Archived from the original (PDF) on January 13, 2013. Retrieved November 27, 2013.
- ^ Koehn, Nancy F. (July 31, 2010). "A Call to Fix the Fundamentals (Review of Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy by Raghuram G. Rajan)". The New York Times. Retrieved November 20, 2013.
- ^ a b Lynn, Barry C.; Longman, Phillip (March–April 2010). "Who Broke America's Jobs Machine?". Washington Monthly. March/April 2010. Retrieved August 11, 2014.
- ^ Castells-Quintana, David; Royuela, Vicente (2012). "Unemployment and long-run economic growth: The role of income inequality and urbanisation" (PDF). Investigaciones Regionales. 12 (24): 153–73. hdl:10017/27066. Retrieved October 17, 2013.
- ^ The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Part I, Section III, Chapter II
- ^ Luxury Fever Archived June 13, 2013, at the Wayback Machine (excerpt)| milkeninstitute.org
- ^ Economist Robert Frank at the Commonwealth Club MPR June 26, 2009, 12:00 p.m.
- ^ Galor, Oded (2011). "Inequality, Human Capital Formation, and the Process of Development". Handbook of the Economics of Education. Elsevier.
- ^ Berg, Andrew G.; Ostry, Jonathan D. (2011). "Equality and Efficiency". Finance and Development. International Monetary Fund. 48 (3).
- ^ Berg, Andrew; Ostry, Jonathan (2017). "Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin". IMF Economic Review. 65 (4): 792–815. doi:10.1057/s41308-017-0030-8. S2CID 13027248.
- ^ Kaldor, Nicolas (1955). "Alternative Theories of Distribution". Review of Economic Studies. 23 (2): 83–100. doi:10.2307/2296292. JSTOR 2296292.
- ^ a b Galor, Oded; Zeira, Joseph (1993). "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 60 (1): 35–52. doi:10.2307/2297811. JSTOR 2297811.
- ^ a b Galor, Oded; Zeira, Joseph (1988). "Income Distribution and Investment in Human Capital: Macroeconomics Implications". Working Paper No. 197 (Department of Economics, Hebrew University).
- ^ The World Bank Group (1999). "The Effect of Distribution on Growth" (PDF).
- ^ a b Alesina, Alberto; Rodrik, Dani (1994). "Distributive Politics and Economic Growth". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 109 (2): 65–90. doi:10.2307/2118470. JSTOR 2118470.
- ^ a b Persson, Torsten; Tabellini, Guido (1994). "Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?". American Economic Review. 84 (3): 600–621.
- ^ Galor, Oded; Moav, Omer (2004). "From Physical to Human Capital Accumulation: Inequality and the Process of Development". Review of Economic Studies. 71 (4): 1001–1026. doi:10.1111/j.1467-937x.2004.00312.x.
- ^ a b Temple, Jonathan (1999). "The New Growth Evidence". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (1): 112–56. doi:10.1257/jel.37.1.112.
- ^ a b Clarke, George R.G. (1995). "More evidence on income distribution and growth". Journal of Development Economics. 47 (2): 403–27. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.454.5573. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(94)00069-o.
- ^ Baumol, William J. (2007). "On income distribution and growth". Journal of Policy Modeling. 29 (4): 545–8. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2007.05.004.
- ^ Herzer, Dierk; Vollmer, Sebastian (2013). "Rising top incomes do not raise the tide". Journal of Policy Modeling. 35 (4): 504–19. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2013.02.011.
- ^ a b c d e Berg, Andrew G.; Ostry, Jonathan D. (2011). "Equality and Efficiency". Finance and Development. 48 (3). Retrieved July 13, 2014.
- ^ a b c d Andrew Berg and Jonathan Ostry. (2011) "Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin" IMF Staff Discussion Note No. SDN/11/08 (International Monetary Fund)
- ^ Perotti, Roberto (1996). "Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data say". Journal of Economic Growth. 1 (2): 149–187. doi:10.1007/bf00138861. S2CID 54670343.
- ^ Barro, Robert J. (2000). "Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries". Journal of Economic Growth. 5 (1): 5–32. doi:10.1023/A:1009850119329. S2CID 2089406.
- ^ Ruth-Aida Nahum (February 2, 2005). "Income Inequality and Growth: a Panel Study of Swedish Counties 1960-2000".
- ^ a b Banerjee, Abhijit V.; Duflo, Esther (2003). "Inequality And Growth: What Can The Data Say?". Journal of Economic Growth. 8 (3): 267–99. doi:10.1023/A:1026205114860. S2CID 4673498. Archived from the original on February 24, 2021. Retrieved September 25, 2012.
- ^ Kaldor 1955.
- ^ Easterly, William (2007). "Inequality does cause underdevelopment: Insights from a new instrument". Journal of Development Economics. 84 (2): 755–76. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.192.3781. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.11.002.
- ^ Dabla-Norris, Era; et al. (June 2015). Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: A Global Perspective (PDF). International Monetary Fund. Retrieved June 29, 2015.
- ^ Bagchi, Sutirtha; Svejnar, Jan (2015). "Does wealth inequality matter for growth? The effect of billionaire wealth, income distribution, and poverty". Journal of Comparative Economics. 43 (3): 505–30. doi:10.1016/j.jce.2015.04.002. hdl:10419/89996.
- ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (2009). "The global crisis, social protection and jobs". International Labour Review. 148 (1–2): 1–13. doi:10.1111/j.1564-913x.2009.00046.x.
- ^ Thomas Piketty. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Harvard University Press, 2014. pp. 15-16. ISBN 0-674-43000-X
- ^ Forbes, Kristin J. (2000). "A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and Growth". The American Economic Review. 90 (4): 869–87. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.315.86. doi:10.1257/aer.90.4.869. JSTOR 117312.
- ^ Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press. p. 374. ISBN 978-0-691-16502-8.
- ^ Shin, Inyong (2012). "Income inequality and economic growth" (PDF). Economic Modelling. 29 (5): 2049–2057. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.011. S2CID 73696536.
- ^ Muhammad Dandume Yusuf (February 2, 2013). "Corruption, Inequality of Income and economic Growth in Nigeria".
- ^ Staff (December 9, 2014). "Inequality hurts economic growth, finds OECD research". Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Retrieved February 8, 2015.
- ^ Pedro Cunha Neves, Óscar Afonso and Sandra Tavares Silva (2016). "A Meta-Analytic Reassessment of the Effects of Inequality on Growth". World Development. 78 (C): 386–400. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.10.038. Retrieved September 24, 2018.
- ^ Castells-Quintana, David; Royuela, Vicente (2017). "Tracking positive and negative effects of inequality on long-run growth". Empirical Economics. 53 (4): 1349–1378. doi:10.1007/s00181-016-1197-y. hdl:2445/54655. S2CID 6489636.
- ^ Brückner, Markus; Lederman, Daniel (2015). "Effects of income inequality on economic growth". VOX CEPR Policy Portal.
- ^ Brückner, Markus; Lederman, Daniel (2018). "Inequality and economic growth: the role of initial income". Journal of Economic Growth. 23 (3): 341–366. doi:10.1007/s10887-018-9156-4. hdl:10986/29896. S2CID 55619830.
- ^ a b Perotti, Roberto (1996). "Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say". Journal of Economic Growth. 1 (2): 149–187. doi:10.1007/bf00138861. S2CID 54670343.
- ^ Bénabou, Roland (1996). "Inequality and Growth". NBER Macroeconomics Annual. 11: 11–92. doi:10.2307/3585187. JSTOR 3585187.
- ^ Berg, Andrew; Ostry, Jonathan D.; Tsangarides, Charalambos G.; Yakhshilikov, Yorbol (2018). "Redistribution, inequality, and growth: new evidence". Journal of Economic Growth. 23 (3): 259–305. doi:10.1007/s10887-017-9150-2. S2CID 158898163.
- ^ "Is Inequality Necessary?" by Timothy Noah, The New Republic December 20, 2011
- ^ a b Claire Melamed, Kate Higgins and Andy Sumner (2010) Economic growth and the MDGs Archived 2011-07-17 at the Wayback Machine Overseas Development Institute
- ^ Anand, Rahul; et al. (August 17, 2013). "Inclusive growth revisited: Measurement and evolution". VoxEU.org. Centre for Economic Policy Research. Retrieved January 13, 2015.
- ^ Anand, Rahul; et al. (May 2013). "Inclusive Growth: Measurement and Determinants" (PDF). IMF Working Paper. Asia Pacific Department: International Monetary Fund. Retrieved January 13, 2015.
- ^ Ranieri, Rafael; Ramos, Raquel Almeida (March 2013). "Inclusive Growth: Building up a Concept". EconStor. hdl:10419/71821.
- ^ Bourguignon, Francois, "Growth Elasticity of Poverty Reduction: Explaining Heterogeneity across Countries and Time Periods" in Inequality and Growth, Ch. 1.
- ^ Ravallion, M. (2007) Inequality is bad for the poor in S. Jenkins and J. Micklewright, (eds.) Inequality and Poverty Re-examined, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
- ^ Elena Ianchovichina and Susanna Lundstrom, 2009. "Inclusive growth analytics: Framework and application", Policy Research Working Paper Series 4851, The World Bank.
- ^ Fabienne, Ilzkovitz; Dierx, Adriaan (June 19, 2016). "Competition policy and inclusive growth". VOX EU. CEPR. Retrieved June 19, 2016.
- ^ "Unexpected connections: Income inequality and environmental degradation". shapingtomorrowsworld.org. 2012-02-13.
- ^ WWF's sustainability and equality paper
- ^ "WWF – Living Planet Report". panda.org.
- ^ Clemente, Jude. "Urbanization: Reducing Poverty and Helping the Environment". Forbes. Retrieved February 19, 2018.
- ^ Dorling, Danny (4 July 2017). "Is inequality bad for the environment?". The Guardian. Retrieved 26 July 2019.
- ^ Mikkelson, Gregory (2007). "Economic Inequality Predicts Biodiversity Loss". PLOS One. 2 (5): e444. Bibcode:2007PLoSO...2..444M. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0000444. PMC 1864998. PMID 17505535.
- ^ Bram Lancee and Hermanvande Werfhorst (2011) "Income Inequality and Participation: A Comparison of 24 European Countries" GINI Discussion Paper No. 6 (Amsterdam Centre for Inequality Studies)
- ^ The Equality Trust (2012) "Income Inequality and Participation"[permanent dead link] Research Update No. 4
- ^ Lahtinen, Hannu; Wass, Hanna; Hiilamo, Heikki (2017). "Gradient constraint in voting: The effect of intra-generational social class and income mobility on turnout" (PDF). Electoral Studies. 45: 14–23. doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2016.11.001. hdl:10138/297763.
- ^ Scheve, Kenneth; Stasavage, David (2017). "Wealth Inequality and Democracy". Annual Review of Political Science. 20 (1): 451–68. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-061014-101840.
- ^ Alesina, A.; Rodrik, D. (1994). "Distributive Politics and Economic Growth". The Quarterly Journal of Economics (Submitted manuscript). 109 (2): 465–90. doi:10.2307/2118470. JSTOR 2118470.
- ^ Espuelas, Sergio (2015). "The inequality trap. A comparative analysis of social spending between 1880 and 1930". The Economic History Review. 68 (2): 683–706. doi:10.1111/1468-0289.12062. hdl:2445/107808. S2CID 11900803.
- ^ Alesina, Alberto; Perotti, Roberto (1996). "Income distribution, political instability, and investment". European Economic Review (Submitted manuscript). 40 (6): 1203–28. doi:10.1016/0014-2921(95)00030-5. S2CID 51838517.
- ^ Ezcurra, Roberto; Palacios, David (2016). "Terrorism and spatial disparities: Does interregional inequality matter?". European Journal of Political Economy. 42: 60–74. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2016.01.004.
- ^ Houle, Christian (2016). "Why class inequality breeds coups but not civil wars". Journal of Peace Research. 53 (5): 680–95. doi:10.1177/0022343316652187. S2CID 113899326.
- ^ "It's Harder Than It Looks To Link Inequality With Global Turmoil". FiveThirtyEight. 2016-01-07. Retrieved January 8, 2016.
- ^ Motesharrei, Safa; Rivas, Jorge; Kalnay, Eugenia (2014). "Human and nature dynamics (HANDY): Modeling inequality and use of resources in the collapse or sustainability of societies". Ecological Economics. 101: 90–102. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.02.014.
- ^ Milanovic, Branko (2016). Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization. Harvard University Press. p. 96. ISBN 978-0-674-73713-6. Archived from the original on 2020-01-25. Retrieved 2018-11-17.