John Ramsay McCulloch (1 March 1789 – 11 November 1864) was a Scottish economist, author and editor, widely regarded as the leader of the Ricardian school of economists after the death of David Ricardo in 1823. He was appointed the first professor of political economy at University College London in 1828. He wrote extensively on economic policy, and was a pioneer in the collection, statistical analysis and publication of economic data.
John Ramsay McCulloch | |
---|---|
Born | Whithorn, Wigtownshire, Scotland, Kingdom of Great Britain | 1 March 1789
Died | 11 November 1864 London, England, United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland | (aged 75)
Nationality | Scottish |
Academic career | |
Field | Political economy |
School or tradition | Classical economics |
Influences | Adam Smith, David Ricardo |
McCulloch was a co-founder, and one of the first editors, of The Scotsman newspaper, and worked on the Edinburgh Review. He edited the 1828 edition of The Wealth of Nations.[1]
Career
editMcCulloch attended the University of Edinburgh, but did not graduate.[2]
McCulloch collected the early literature of political economy, and wrote on the scope and method of economics and the history of economic thought.[3][4] After his death his library was purchased by Lord Overstone and eventually presented to the University of Reading. He was a participant in the Political Economy Club, London, founded by James Mill[5] and a circle of friends in 1821 for an ongoing discussion of the fundamental principles of political economy.
McCulloch's works include a textbook, Principles of Political Economy (Edinburgh 1825). He worked on subsequent editions until his death. This book contains a memorable discussion of the origins of profit or interest in the case of a cask of new wine.
- "Suppose that a cask of new wine, which cost £50, is put into a cellar, and that, at the end of twelve months, it is worth £55, the question is: Should the £5 of additional value, given to the wine, be considered as a compensation for the time the £50 worth of capital has been locked up, or should it be considered as the value of additional labour actually laid out in the wine?"
This question is still used in discussions of the labour theory of value and related issues. McCulloch used it to illustrate that "time cannot of itself produce effect; it merely affords space for really efficient causes to operate, and it is therefore clear it can have nothing to do with value." Reflecting on discussions in the Political Economy Club, Ricardo had privately expressed his famous opinion about the "non-existence of any measure of absolute value."[6]
McCulloch was an opponent of Robert Malthus, in response to Malthus's Definitions in Political Economy (1827) wherein Malthus criticized several contemporary economists, including Jean-Baptiste Say, James Mill, and McCulloch, for what he considered sloppiness in selection of, attachment of meaning to, and usage of their technical terms.[7] In March 1827 McCulloch made a cutting reply on the front page of his Edinburgh newspaper, The Scotsman,[8] implying that Malthus wanted to dictate terms and theories to other economists. McCulloch clearly felt his ox gored, and his review of Definitions is largely a bitter defence of his own Principles of Political Economy,[9] and his counter-attack "does little credit to his reputation", being largely "personal derogation" of Malthus.[10] The purpose of Malthus's Definitions was terminological clarity, and Malthus discussed appropriate terms, their definitions, and their use by himself and his contemporaries. This motivation of Malthus's work was disregarded by McCulloch, who responded that there was nothing to be gained "by carping at definitions, and quibbling about the meaning to be attached to" words. Given that statement, it is not surprising that McCulloch's review failed to address the rules of chapter 1 and did not discuss the definitions of chapter 10; he also barely mentioned Malthus's critiques of other writers.[7]
McCulloch died in 1864, and is buried in Brompton Cemetery, London.
Criticism
editMcCulloch's theoretical work received harsh criticism from Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk in the latter's History and Critique of Interest Theories (1884).
- "But probably no member of the English school has been so unhappy in his treatment of the subject or done the theory of interest such a disservice as McCulloch,"
wrote Böhm-Bawerk.
- "He hovers about the fringes of a number of divergent opinions. He penetrates just far enough into each to become involved in glaring self-contradictions, but he does not expand any one of them sufficiently to form a theory that even approaches consistency."
The labour theory of value is an exception, in that McCulloch seems more insistent about it than about any of the contradictory hypotheses he entertained, Böhm-Bawerk conceded, but the form of that theory McCulloch endorsed was "the most absurd that could possibly occur to a serious thinker."
On the subject of the wine cask, Böhm-Bawerk wrote that there was an "enormous difference between what he was supposed to prove and what he did prove." Although such examples may prove that the mere passage of time is not enough of a change to produce an increase of value, that hardly helps the labour theory of value. The physical changes in the wine are produced by the microbes involved in the fermentation process, and the change in exchange value involves the public's subjective preference for wine over grape juice, and old wine over new.
Works
edit- An Essay on a Reduction of the Interest of the National Debt, 1816.
- "On Ricardo's Principles of Political Economy and Taxation", 1818, Edinburgh Review
- "Taxation and the Corn Laws", 1820, Edinburgh Review
- "The Opinions of Messrs. Say, Sismondi and Malthus, on Effects of Machinery and Accumulation", 1821, Edinburgh Review
- "On Combination Laws, Restraints on Emigration, &c.", 1824, Edinburgh Review
- "Political Economy", 1824, Encyclopædia Britannica.
- "French Law of Succession", 1824, Edinburgh Review.
- McCulloch (1824). A Discourse of the Rise, Progress, Peculiar Objects, and Importance, of Political Economy: containing an Outline of a Course of Lectures on the Principles and Doctrines of that Science. Edinburgh, London, Liverpool: Archibald Constable & Co, Hurst, Robinson & Co, G. & J. Robinson. OCLC 309905804.[11][12] 2nd edition 1825. OCLC 7391021[13]
- The Principles of Political Economy, with a sketch of the rise and progress of the science. 1825.[14]
- An Essay on the Circumstances which Determine the Rate of Wages and the Condition of the Working Classes, 1826.
- "On Commercial Revulsions", 1826, Edinburgh Review
- "Abolition of the Corn Laws", 1826, Edinburgh Review
- "On Poor Laws", 1828, Edinburgh Review
- "Rise, Progress, Present State, and Prospects of the British Cotton Manufacture", 1827, Edinburgh Review.
- "Introduction" to An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith, (ed. J.R. McCulloch), 1828.
- "Jones on the Theory of Rent", Edinburgh Review, 1831.
- Principles, Practice and History of Commerce, 1831.
- "Chalmers on Political Economy", 1832, Edinburgh Review.
- A Dictionary, Practical, Theoretical and Historical of Commerce and Commercial Navigation, 1832.
- A Descriptive and Statistical Account of the British Empire, exhibiting its extent, physical capacities, population, industry, and civil and religious institutions. 2 volumes, 1837
- Statements Illustrative of the Policy and Probable Consequence of the Proposed Repeal of the Existing Corn Law, 1841.
- The Literature of Political Economy, 1845.
- The Works of David Ricardo, Esq. with a notice of the life and writings of the author (ed. J.R. McCulloch), 1846.
- A Treatise on the Succession to Property Vacant by Death, 1848.
- A Treatise on Metallic and Paper Money and Banks, 1858
- Treatises and Essays, 1859.
- A Treatise on the Principles and Practical Influence of Taxation and the Funding System, 1863.
References
editNotes
edit- ^ "John Ramsay McCulloch". Gazetteer for Scotland. Retrieved 13 May 2010.
- ^ Goring, Rosemary, ed. (1992). Chambers Scottish Biographical Dictionary. Edinburgh: Chambers.
- ^ McCulloch1824.
- ^ J. R. McCulloch, Early English Tracts on Commerce. London: Political Economy Club (1856); Cambridge [Eng.] University Press, 1954.
- ^ ""James Mill, 1773–1836", New School". Archived from the original on 3 April 2008. Retrieved 4 April 2009.
- ^ Ricardo to Malthus, 15 August 1823. Quoted by Halevy, The Growth of Philosophic Radicalism, Beacon Press, (1955) p. 352.
- ^ a b Malthus, Thomas Robert (2016). Definitions in Political Economy. McLean: Berkeley Bridge Press. ISBN 978-1-945208-01-0.
- ^ McCulloch, John Ramsay (10 March 1827). "A Review of Definitions in Political Economy by the Rev. T. R. Malthus". The Scotsman: 1.
- ^ McCulloch, John Ramsay (1825). The Principles of Political Economy. Edinburgh: William & Charles Tait.
- ^ Morton Paglin's "Introduction" to: Malthus, Thomas Robert (1986). Definitions in Political Economy. Fairfield, New Jersey: Augustus M. Kelley. p. xiii.
- ^ Discourse 1824: pdf Archived 9 June 2007 at the Wayback Machine at McMaster
- ^ Discourse 1824 at the Internet Archive
- ^ Discourse 2nd. ed. 1825 at the Internet Archive; id. at the Internet Archive
- ^ The Principles of Political Economy (1825) in Google books
Sources
edit- Denis P. O'Brien, J. R. McCulloch, A Study in Classical Economics, George Allen & Unwin (1970). ISBN 0-04-330158-4.
- Collected works of J R McCulloch, with introductions by Denis O'Brien. 8 volumes. Routledge/Thoemmes Press (1995). ISBN 978-0415113526.
External links
edit- Media related to John Ramsay McCulloch at Wikimedia Commons
- 1902 Encyclopædia Britannica: John Ramsay McCulloch
- Chisholm, Hugh, ed. (1911). . Encyclopædia Britannica. Vol. 17 (11th ed.). Cambridge University Press. pp. 208–209.
- John Ramsay McCulloch at the website of "The History of Economic Thought" (HET)