Slutsky equation

(Redirected from Slutsky matrix)

In microeconomics, the Slutsky equation (or Slutsky identity), named after Eugen Slutsky, relates changes in Marshallian (uncompensated) demand to changes in Hicksian (compensated) demand, which is known as such since it compensates to maintain a fixed level of utility.

There are two parts of the Slutsky equation, namely the substitution effect, and income effect. In general, the substitution effect can be negative for consumers as it can limit choices. He designed this formula to explore a consumer's response as the price changes. When the price increases, the budget set moves inward, which also causes the quantity demanded to decrease. In contrast, when the price decreases, the budget set moves outward, which leads to an increase in the quantity demanded. The substitution effect is due to the effect of the relative price change while the income effect is due to the effect of income being freed up. The equation demonstrates that the change in the demand for a good, caused by a price change, is the result of two effects:

  • a substitution effect: when the price of good changes, as it becomes relatively cheaper, if hypothetically consumer's consumption remains same, income would be freed up which could be spent on a combination of each or more of the goods.
  • an income effect: the purchasing power of a consumer increases as a result of a price decrease, so the consumer can now afford better products or more of the same products, depending on whether the product itself is a normal good or an inferior good.

The Slutsky equation decomposes the change in demand for good i in response to a change in the price of good j:

where is the Hicksian demand and is the Marshallian demand, at the vector of price levels , wealth level (or, alternatively, income level) , and fixed utility level given by maximizing utility at the original price and income, formally given by the indirect utility function . The right-hand side of the equation is equal to the change in demand for good i holding utility fixed at u minus the quantity of good j demanded, multiplied by the change in demand for good i when wealth changes.

The first term on the right-hand side represents the substitution effect, and the second term represents the income effect.[1] Note that since utility is not observable, the substitution effect is not directly observable, but it can be calculated by reference to the other two terms in the Slutsky equation, which are observable. This process is sometimes known as the Hicks decomposition of a demand change.[2]

The equation can be rewritten in terms of elasticity:

where εp is the (uncompensated) price elasticity, εph is the compensated price elasticity, εw,i the income elasticity of good i, and bj the budget share of good j.

Overall, in simple words, the Slutsky equation states the total change in demand consists of an income effect and a substitution effect and both effects collectively must equal the total change in demand.

The equation above is helpful as it represents the fluctuation in demand are indicative of different types of good. The substitution effect will always turn out negative as indifference curves are always downward sloping. However, the same does not apply to income effect as it depends on how consumption of a good changes with income.

The income effect on a normal goods is negative, and if the price decreases, consequently purchasing power or income goes up. The reverse holds when price increases and purchasing power or income decreases, as a result of, so does demand.

Generally, not all goods are "normal". While in an economic sense, some are inferior. However, that does not equate quality-wise that they are poor rather that it sets a negative income profile - as income increases, consumers consumption of the good decreases.

For example, consumers who are running low of money for food purchase instant noodles, however, the product is not generally held as something people would normally consume on a daily basis. This is due to the constrains in terms of money; as wealth increases, consumption decreases. In this case, the substitution effect is negative, but the income effect is also negative.

In any case the substitution effect or income effect are positive or negative when prices increase depends on the type of goods:

Total Effect Substitution Effect Income Effect
+ Substitute goods Substitute goods Inferior goods
- Complementary goods Complementary goods Normal goods

However, whether the total effect will always be negative is impossible to tell if inferior complementary goods are mentioned. For instance, the substitution effect and the income effect pull in opposite directions. The total effect will depend on which effect is ultimately stronger.

Derivation

edit

While there are several ways to derive the Slutsky equation, the following method is likely the simplest. Begin by noting the identity   where   is the expenditure function, and u is the utility obtained by maximizing utility given p and w. Totally differentiating with respect to pj yields as the following:

 .

Making use of the fact that   by Shephard's lemma and that at optimum,

  where   is the indirect utility function,

one can substitute and rewrite the derivation above as the Slutsky equation.

The Slutsky matrix

edit

The Slutsky equation can be rewritten in matrix form:

 

where Dp is the derivative operator with respect to prices and Dw is the derivative operator with respect to wealth.

The matrix   is known as the Hicksian substitution matrix and is formally defined as:

 

The Slutsky matrix is given by:

 

When   is the maximum utility the consumer achieves at prices   and income  , that is,  , the Slutsky equation implies that each element of the Slutsky matrix   is exactly equal to the corresponding element of the Hicksian substitution matrix  . The Slutsky matrix is symmetric, and given that the expenditure function   is concave, the Slutsky matrix is also negative semi-definite.

Example

edit

A Cobb-Douglas utility function (see Cobb-Douglas production function) with two goods and income   generates Marshallian demand for goods 1 and 2 of   and   Rearrange the Slutsky equation to put the Hicksian derivative on the left-hand-side yields the substitution effect:

 

Going back to the original Slutsky equation shows how the substitution and income effects add up to give the total effect of the price rise on quantity demanded:

 

Thus, of the total decline of   in quantity demanded when   rises, 21/70 is from the substitution effect and 49/70 from the income effect. Good 1 is the good this consumer spends most of his income on ( ), which is why the income effect is so large.

One can check that the answer from the Slutsky equation is the same as from directly differentiating the Hicksian demand function, which here is[3]

 

where   is utility. The derivative is

 

so since the Cobb-Douglas indirect utility function is   and   when the consumer uses the specified demand functions, the derivative is:

 

which is indeed the Slutsky equation's answer.

The Slutsky equation also can be applied to compute the cross-price substitution effect. One might think it was zero here because when   rises, the Marshallian quantity demanded of good 1,   is unaffected ( ), but that is wrong. Again rearranging the Slutsky equation, the cross-price substitution effect is:

 

This says that when   rises, there is a substitution effect of   towards good 1. At the same time, the rise in   has a negative income effect on good 1's demand, an opposite effect of the exact same size as the substitution effect, so the net effect is zero. This is a special property of the Cobb-Douglas function.

Changes in multiple prices at once

edit

When there are two goods, the Slutsky equation in matrix form is:[4]

 

Although strictly speaking the Slutsky equation only applies to infinitesimal changes in prices, it is standardly used a linear approximation for finite changes. If the prices of the two goods change by   and  , the effect on the demands for the two goods are:

 

Multiplying out the matrices, the effect on good 1, for example, would be

 

The first term is the substitution effect. The second term is the income effect, composed of the consumer's response to income loss times the size of the income loss from each price's increase.

Giffen goods

edit

A Giffen good is a product that is in greater demand when the price increases, which are also special cases of inferior goods.[5] In the extreme case of income inferiority, the size of income effect overpowers the size of the substitution effect, leading to a positive overall change in demand responding to an increase in the price. Slutsky's decomposition of the change in demand into a pure substitution effect and income effect explains why the law of demand doesn't hold for Giffen goods.

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ Nicholson, W. (2005). Microeconomic Theory (10th ed.). Mason, Ohio: Thomson Higher Education.
  2. ^ Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton.
  3. ^ Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton., p. 121.
  4. ^ Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton., pp. 120-121.
  5. ^ Varian, Hal R. “Chapter 8: Slutsky Equation.” Essay. In Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus, 1st ed., 137. New York, NY: W W Norton, 2014.

References

edit

Varian, H. R. (2020). Intermediate microeconomics : a modern approach (Ninth edition.). W.W. Norton & Company.