This article needs additional citations for verification. (October 2018) |
The fair trade debate concerns the ethics and economic implications of fair trade, a term for an arrangement designed to help producers in developing countries achieve sustainable and equitable trade relationships. The benefits of fair trade for farmers and workers can vary considerably and the social transformation impacts also vary around the world.[1] However the main concerns from critics is that fair trade may give an unfair advantage to some producers over others.
Fairtrade researcher Alastair Smith argues that while some criticisms are grounded in acceptable standards of evidence (and deserve serious attention), others are less well elaborated,[2] and that in a few cases the criticisms presented are assertions with little or no credible evidence to support them.[3] These claims have themselves been criticized on matters of fact, theory, methodology, use of evidence and incorrect citations.[4]: 45–49 [5]
Fair trade income
editOne study concluded that benefits of fair trade to producers were close to zero because there was an oversupply of certification, and only a fraction of produce classified as Fair Trade was actually sold on Fair Trade markets, just enough to recoup the costs of certification.[6] A study published by the Journal of Economic Perspectives however suggests that Fair Trade does achieve many of its intended goals, although on a comparatively modest scale relative to the size of national economies.[7]
Consumers buy fair trade goods for a variety of reasons; some are willing to pay more for Fairtrade certified products in the belief that this helps the very poor.[8] Critics of the Fairtrade brand have argued that the system diverts profits from the poorest farmers, that the profit is received by corporate firms, and that this causes "death and destitution".[9]
Evidence suggests that little of the extra money paid by consumers actually reaches the farmers. The Fairtrade Foundation does not monitor how much extra retailers charge for Fairtrade goods. Furthermore, retailers almost never sell identical Fairtrade and non-Fairtrade lines side by side, so it is rarely possible to determine how much extra is charged and so how much of that premium reaches the producers.[10] In a very few cases, it has been possible to find out. One British café chain was passing less than one percent of the extra charged to the exporting cooperative;[9] in Finland, Valkila, Haaparanta, and Niemi[11] found that consumers paid much more for Fairtrade, but that only 11.5% of that reached the exporter. Kilian, Jones, Pratt, and Villalobos[12] say U.S. Fairtrade coffee gets US$5 per pound extra at retail, of which the exporter receives only 2%. Mendoza and Bastiaensen[13] calculated that in the UK only 1.6% to 18% of the extra charged for one product line reached the farmer. Critics claim that many counter-examples would be needed to show that these are not typical. Since Fairtrade charges a 1.9% licensing fee at wholesale, the maximum that reaches the developing world, even if traders charge unrealistically low margins, is 50%, and a much smaller amount would reach the target farmers.
The Fairtrade Foundation does not monitor how much of the premium paid to the exporting cooperatives reaches the farmer. Cooperatives incur certification and inspection fees, additional marketing costs, costs in meeting the Fairtrade political standards, and possibly costs arising from the monopoly power of the cooperative. Farmers also incur additional production costs on their production, even if only a small amount is sold at Fairtrade prices. Over the years, Fairtrade producers have been able to sell only 18% to 37% of their output as Fairtrade certified, selling the rest without certification at market prices. While both proponents and opponents of Fairtrade acknowledge this problem,[14][15] there are scarce economic studies presenting the actual revenues of Fairtrade cooperatives and how they spend their money. Weber (2006) examined the additional marketing costs of some cooperatives and found, for example, that "after six years Oro Verde can cover only 70 percent of its [additional marketing] costs with its current income stream" and that the cooperative needs to double its current annual export volume in order to sustain its management team. At the time they were losing money on their Fairtrade membership.[16] FLO figures[17] show that 40% of the money reaching the developing world is spent on "business and production," which includes the costs mentioned above as well as costs incurred by inefficiency and corruption in the cooperative or the marketing system. The rest is spent on social projects, rather than being passed on to farmers.
There is no evidence[citation needed] that Fairtrade farmers get higher prices on average.Farmers are allegedly paid more by traders than by Fairtrade cooperatives while others state that they were paid less. Few such anecdotes address the problems of price reporting in developing world markets,[18] or appreciate the complexity of different price packages. A different price package may or may not include credit, harvesting, transport, processing, etc. Cooperatives typically average prices over the year, so they may pay more or less than traders, depending on the day. Basset compares prices only where Fairtrade and non-Fairtrade farmers have to sell cotton to the same monopsonistic ginneries, which pay low prices.[19] Prices would have to be higher to compensate farmers for the increased costs of producing Fairtrade. For instance, when Fairtrade encouraged Nicaraguan farmers to switch to organic coffee, they earned a higher price per pound but a lower net income because of higher costs and lower yields.[20][12][21]
Fair trade research
editSome critics argue that there have been few fair trade impact studies to confirm the benefits claimed and there have been calls for more evaluations as the movement has grown. A 2009 literature review[22] found 33 studies that met the criteria for impact studies. Griffiths (2011)[9] says that few meet the normal standards for an impact evaluation, such as comparing the before and after situation, having meaningful control groups, and allowing for the facts that Fairtrade recruits farmers who are already better off, that a Fairtrade cooperative receives aid from other organizations (government departments, aid agencies, donor countries, and NGOs), and that Fairtrade may harm other farmers. Other methodological problems arise in sampling, in comparing prices, and from the fact that the social projects of Fairtrade do not usually aim to produce economic benefits.
Due to the snapshot nature of research, few studies include how long producers have been involved with fair trade. A further problem is that most studies ignore the agency and perspective of producer decision makers, especially those farmers excluded from the Fairtrade system. Capturing such socially constructed benefits, including that of confidence in business relationships, is difficult.
There is a difference between impact studies and case studies.[4]: 40–96 Case studies are valuable for, among other things, researching specific systems and sub-systems, constructing models, and identifying problems. However, the impacts noted cannot be extrapolated generally. For instance, if a hundred dairy farms lose money, this does not mean that all or most dairy farms do. There are a lot of case studies on Fairtrade, but many are erroneously referred to as impact studies.
Fair trade market issues
editOne reason for low prices[clarification needed] is that Fairtrade farmers are forced to sell through a monopsonist cooperative, which may be inefficient or corrupt. They cannot choose the buyer who offers the best price, or switch when their cooperative is going bankrupt.[23] Fairtrade deviates from the free market ideal of some economists. Brink calls fair trade a "misguided attempt to make up for market failures" that encourages market inefficiencies and overproduction.[24] Sometimes goods are overproduced, leading to the sale of a fair trade product in a non-fair trade market, causing potential issues with customers who are paying for fair trade products despite the fact that the same products are available for lower amounts.[25]
Critics argue that Fairtrade, but not all other fair trade businesses, harms non-Fairtrade farmers. Fairtrade claims that its farmers are paid higher prices and are given special advice on better techniques, both of which lead to increased output being sold on the global market. Economists[26][27] assert that, as the demand for coffee is highly inelastic, an increased price for Fairtrade which produces a small increase in supply means a large fall in market price. In addition, the Fairtrade minimum price means that when the world market price collapses, it is the non-Fairtrade farmers, particularly the poorest, who have to cut down their coffee trees. This argument is illustrated with the example of Vietnam paying its coffee farmers above the world market price in the 1980s, planting much coffee, then flooding the world market in the 1990s.[4] Smith (2010) questioned the relevance of the Vietnam example,[28] and Griffiths later published a response.[5]
Low prices may also occur because the fair trade marketing system provides more opportunities for corruption than the normal marketing system, and less possibility of, or incentive for, controlling it. Corruption has been noted in false labeling of coffee as Fairtrade by retailers and by packers in the developing countries,[29] importers paying exporters less than the Fairtrade price for Fairtrade coffee,[30][31][20] failure by importers to provide the credit and other services specified,[32][23][33][34][35][36] theft or preferential treatment for ruling elites of cooperatives,[13][15] and not paying laborers the specified minimum wage.[29][37][38]
Inequity
editFair trade is profitable for traders in rich countries. It is also aimed at richer farmers: in order to join Fairtrade, cooperatives must meet quality and political standards which means their farmers must be relatively skillful and educated. Critics point out that these farmers are, therefore, far from the poorest farmers. The majority of Fairtrade suppliers are in the higher income or middle income developing countries, such as Costa Rica and Mexico, with relatively few in the poorest countries. Mexico has 70 times the GNP per capita as Sierra Leone, and much larger coffee farms. The minimum wage of agricultural workers in Peru is US$3 per day and the average income of Fairtrade farmers in Bolivia was US$900/year, much higher than normal agricultural incomes in Africa and much of Asia. Critics say this diverts money from the poorest farmers.[9]
Fairtrade supporters boast of "the honeypot effect": that cooperatives which become Fairtrade members then attract additional aid from other NGO charities, government, and international donors as a result of their membership.[39][40][41] Typically this results in six to twelve other donors. Critics point out that this inevitably means that resources are being removed from other, poorer, farmers. It also makes it difficult to discern whether any positive or negative changes can be attributed specifically to either Fairtrade or one of the other donors.
Some research indicates that the implementation of certain fair trade standards can cause greater inequalities in some markets where these rigid rules are inappropriate for the specific market.[26][42][43][44]
Other issues
editPolitical coercion
editThe Fairtrade criteria presuppose a set of political values as to what economic, environmental, and social problems exist and how they are to be solved. Critics say it is unethical to bribe developing world producers to act according to political viewpoints that they may not agree with, and that the consumers providing the money may not agree with. These critics also state that the unorthodox marketing system imposed, which aims to replace capitalism, may not tie in with the objectives of producers, consumers, importers, or retailers.[26][42][44][45][46][47]
Booth says that the selling techniques used by some sellers and supporters of Fairtrade are bullying, misleading, and unethical.[26][45][48] Boycott campaigns and other pressure force sellers to stock a product they think ethically suspect. However, the opposite has been argued, that a more participatory and multi-stakeholder approach to auditing might improve the quality of the process.[clarification needed][49] Some people[who?] argue that these practices are justifiable: strategic use of labeling may embarrass (or encourage) major suppliers into changing their practices. They may bring to light corporate vulnerabilities that activists can exploit. Or they may encourage ordinary people to get involved with broader projects of social change.[50]
Volunteers may do unpaid work for fair trade firms, or promote fair trade organizations in schools and local governments, often without full awareness that these are not non-profit organizations. Davies and Crane[51] report that Day Chocolate "made considerable use of unpaid volunteer workers for routine tasks, many of whom seemed to be under the (false) impression that they were helping out a charity. Not only might one question the sometimes quite excessive use of unpaid labour in a for-profit organisation, but the management team at Day appeared to have no intention of correcting the obvious misapprehensions of the volunteers. However, this did not appear to be acknowledged as a potential ethical problem at Day."
There have been complaints that Fairtrade standards are inappropriate and may harm producers, sometimes imposing months of additional work for little return.[38][14][52]
Failure to enforce standards
editChristian Jacquiau and Paola Ghillani (who spent four years as president of Fairtrade Labelling Organizations) claim that adherence to fair trade standards by producers has been poor and that enforcement of standards by Fairtrade is weak.[53] Labourers on Fairtrade farms in Peru are paid less than the minimum wage;[54] some non-Fairtrade coffee is sold as Fairtrade;[29] "the standards are not very strict in the case of seasonally hired labour in coffee production";[20] "some fair trade standards are not strictly enforced";[36] and supermarkets may avoid their responsibility.[32] In 2006, a Financial Times journalist found that all ten out of the ten mills they visited had sold uncertified coffee to co-operatives as certified. It reported on "evidence of at least one coffee association that received Fairtrade certification despite illegally growing some 20 per cent of its coffee in protected national forest land.[29]
False advertising
editAnother criticism is that false claims made for fair trade and the withholding of relevant information constitute Unfair Trading under EU law.[26][9][42][44][45]
Under EU law (Directive 2005/29/EC on Unfair Commercial Practices) the criminal offence of Unfair Trading is committed if (a) advertising or selling information "contains false information and is therefore untruthful or in any way, including overall presentation, deceives or is likely to deceive the average consumer, even if the information is factually correct", (b) "it omits material information that the average consumer needs… and thereby causes or is likely to cause the average consumer to take a transactional decision that he would not have taken otherwise" or (c) "fails to identify the commercial intent of the commercial practice… [which] causes or is likely to cause the average consumer to take a transactional decision that he would not have taken otherwise."[10] Griffiths (2011)[9] points to false claims that Fairtrade producers get higher prices, the almost universal failures to disclose the extra price charged for Fairtrade products, to disclose how much of this actually reaches the developing world, to disclose what this is spent on in the developing world, to disclose how much (if any) reaches farmers, and to disclose the harm that Fairtrade does to non-Fairtrade farmers. He also points to the failure to disclose when "the primary commercial intent" is to make money for retailers and distributors
Trade justice and fair trade
editSegments of the trade justice movement have also criticized fair trade for focusing too much on individual small producer groups without advocating trade policy changes that would have a larger impact on disadvantaged producers' lives. RFI correspondent Jean-Pierre Boris championed this view in his 2005 book Commerce inéquitable.[55]
Political objections
editPolitical criticisms of Fairtrade come from both the left and the right. Some believe the fair trade system is not radical enough. French author Christian Jacquiau, in his book Les coulisses du commerce équitable, calls for stricter fair trade standards and criticizes the fair trade movement for working within the current system (i.e. partnerships with mass retailers, multinational corporations, etc.) rather than establishing a new fairer, fully autonomous trading system. Jacquiau also supports significantly higher fair trade prices in order to maximize the impact, as most producers only sell a portion of their crop under fair trade terms.[56] It has been argued that the FairTrade system is too rooted in a Northern consumerist view of justice which Southern producers do not participate in. "A key issue is therefore to make explicit who possesses the power to define the terms of Fairtrade, that is who possesses the power to determine the need of an ethic in the first instance, and subsequently command a particular ethical vision as the truth."[57] Some free market criticisms of Fairtrade appear to be linked[weasel words] to right wing political approaches, but this does not mean that their analysis in this particular case is unacceptable to mainstream economists.
Counter-arguments
editKey ideas of fair trade include transparency and capacity building, as outlined by the WFTO fair trade principles. Particularly in the developing world, it is common for small-scale farmers to have only one or two buyers for their commodity products. Prices thus can be set by the buyers along with quality criteria. Normally buyers do not provide transparency as to the weighing and grading of product. Unless the buyers are linked to a quality supply chain (such as a fair trade or organic supply chain), the buyers normally do not provide any capacity-building to improve the quality of the product and thus gain a higher price. Fair trade, when practiced well, must provide full transparency in terms of pricing, weighing, and quality standards. As the end goal is a superior quality product in all ways, good fair trade organizations provide good capacity building in terms of best production, harvest, and post-harvest practices.
Hayes[58] identifies limitations in LeClaire's (2002)[59] formulation of this, both using what they agree is an unrealistic model.[clarification needed]
See also
editSources
edit- ^ Linton, April (2012). Fair trade from the ground up: new markets for social justice. Seattle, Wash.: Univ. of Washington Press. ISBN 978-0-295-99172-6.
- ^ Smith, Alastair (2008). "A Response to the Adam Smith Report & A New Way to Think About Measuring the Content of the Fair Trade Cup Alastair" (PDF). Comment and Analysis. Retrieved 2012-12-23.
- ^ Smith, Alastair (2008). "Fair Trade, Diversification and Structural Change: Towards a broader theoretical framework of analysis". Oxford Development Studies. 37 (4): 457–478. doi:10.1080/13600810903305208. S2CID 32182452.
- ^ a b c Peter, Griffiths (2011). "Lack of rigour in defending Fairtrade: a reply to Alastair Smith" (PDF). Economic Affairs. 31: 103–104. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0270.2010.02058.x. S2CID 152514399.
- ^ a b Griffiths, P.: 2011, "Rejoinder: False Statements, Misrepresentation and Distortion in Defending Fairtrade", Economic Affairs, pp. 103–04
- ^ de Janvry, Alain; McIntosh, Craig; Sadoulet, Elisabeth (July 2015). "Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool?". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 97 (3): 567–573. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00512. S2CID 27543341.
- ^ Dragusanu, Raluca; Giovannucci, Daniele; Nunn, Nathan (2014). "The Economics of Fair Trade" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 28 (3): 217–236. doi:10.1257/jep.28.3.217. S2CID 31724677. Retrieved 1 April 2020.
- ^ Niemi, N (2010). "Empowering Coffee Traders? The Coffee Value Chain from Nicaraguan Fair Trade Farmers to Finnish Consumers". Journal of Business Ethics. 97 (2): 257–270. doi:10.1007/s10551-010-0508-z. S2CID 146802807.
- Trudel, R., & Cotte, J. (2009). Does it pay to be good? MIT Sloan Management Review, Winter
- Arnot, C.; Boxall, P.; Cash, S. (2006). "Do ethical consumers care about price? A revealed preference analysis of Fair Trade coffee purchases" (PDF). Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics. 54 (4): 555–565. Bibcode:2006CaJAE..54..555A. doi:10.1111/j.1744-7976.2006.00066.x.
- ^ a b c d e f Griffiths, P. (July 2011). "Ethical objections to Fairtrade" (PDF). Journal of Business Ethics. 105 (3): 357–373. doi:10.1007/s10551-011-0972-0. S2CID 153463544. Accessed at Why Fairtrade isn't fair.
- ^ a b Directive 2005/29/EC on Unfair Commercial Practices
- ^ Valkila, Haaparanta & Niemi 2010.
- ^ a b Kilian et al. 2006.
- ^ a b Mendoza, R.; Bastiaensen, J. (2003). "Fair Trade and the Coffee Crisis in the Nicaraguan Segovias". Small Enterprise Development. 14 (2): 36–46. doi:10.3362/0957-1329.2003.020.
- ^ a b Utting-Chamorro, K (2005). "Does Fairtrade make a difference? The case of small coffee producers in Nicaragua". Development in Practice. 15 (3–4): 584–599. doi:10.1080/09614520500075706. S2CID 154018501.
- ^ a b Berndt 2007.
- ^ Weber, J. (2006). "Rationing in the Fair Trade Coffee Market: Who enters and How?" International colloquium on fair trade and sustainable development. Montreal: Ecole des Sciences de la Gestion, Universite du Quebec.
- ^ Fairtrade Labelling Organizations International.: 2010, Annual Report 2009–2010. Retrieved May 27, 2011.
- ^ See Bowbrick, P, "Are price reporting systems of any use?", British Food Journal. 90(2) pp. 65–69 March/April. 1988.
- ^ Bassett, T. (2009). "Slim pickings: Fairtrade cotton in West Africa." Geoforum
- ^ a b c Valkila 2009.
- ^ Wilson, B. R. (2009). "Indebted to Fair Trade? Coffee and Crisis in Nicaragua." Geoforum
- ^ Nelson, V., & Pound, B.: 2009, "The Last Ten Years: A Comprehensive Review of the Literature on the Impact of Fairtrade" Archived 2012-01-26 at the Wayback Machine.
- ^ a b Mendoza & Bastiaensen 2003, p. 42.
- ^ Brink, Lindsey. (2004). "Grounds for Complaint" Archived 2008-05-17 at the Wayback Machine. URL accessed on September 25, 2006.
- ^ de Janvry, A (2015). "Fair Trade and Free Entry: Can a Disequilibrium Market Serve as a Development Tool?". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 97 (3): 567–573. doi:10.1162/rest_a_00512. S2CID 27543341.
- ^ a b c d e Booth, P.; Whetstone, L. (2007). "Half a Cheer for Fair Trade". Economic Affairs. 27 (2): 29–36. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0270.2007.00727.x. S2CID 55272716.
- ^ Griffiths, P. (2008) "Why Fairtrade Isn't Fair", Prospect, August 2008. Accessed at Why Fairtrade isn't fair
- Sidwell, M. (2008) Unfair Trade, London: Adam Smith Institute.
- Brink, Lindsey. (2004). Grounds for Complaint Archived 2008-05-17 at the Wayback Machine. URL accessed on September 25, 2006.
- Hayes, Mark (2008). "Fighting the Tide: Alternative trade organizations in the era of global free trade - A comment". World Development. 36 (12): 2953–2961. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00017-7.
- Harford, T: "The Undercover Economist." 2005. Sam Bowman (11 March 2011). "Markets, poverty, and Fair Trade". Adam Smith Institute. Archived from the original on 2012-04-01. Retrieved 2011-09-30."Voting with your trolley". The Economist. Dec 7, 2006.
- ^ Smith, Fairtrade (2010). "Lack of Rigour on Defending Fairtrade: Some important clarrifications of a distorting account – a reply to Perter Griffiths" (PDF). Economic Affairs. 30 (2): 50–53. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0270.2010.02011.x. S2CID 143300468.
- ^ a b c d Weitzman, H. (September 8, 2006). "The bitter cost of 'fair trade' coffee". Financial Times.
- ^ de Janvry, A., McIntosh, C., & Sadoulet, E. (2010). Fair Trade and Free Entry:The Dissipation of Producer Benefits in a Disequilibrium Market". Retrieved December 24, 2012
- Raynolds, L. T. (2009). "Mainstreaming Fair Trade Coffee: from Partnership to Traceability". World Development. 37 (6): 1089. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.10.001.
- ^ Valkila, Haaparanta & Niemi 2010, p. 264.
- ^ a b Moore, G.; Gibbon, J.; Slack, R. (2006), "The mainstreaming of Fair Trade: a macromarketing perspective" (PDF), Journal of Strategic Marketing, 14 (4): 329–352, doi:10.1080/09652540600947961, S2CID 46523470.
- ^ Reed, D (2009). "What do Corporations have to do with Fair Trade? Positive and normative analysis from a value chain perspective". Journal of Business Ethics. 86: 3–26. doi:10.1007/s10551-008-9757-5. S2CID 55809844.
- ^ Valkila 2009, pp. 3022–3023.
- ^ Barrientos, S., Conroy, M. E., & Jones, E. (2007). Northern Social Movements and Fair Trade. In L. Raynolds, D. D. Murray, & J. Wilkinson, Fair Trade: The Challenges of Transforming Globalization (pp. 51–62). London and New York: Routledge
- Mendoza, R. (2000). The hierarchical legacy in coffee commodity chains. In R. Ruben, & J. Bastiaensen, Rural development in Central America. New York: St. Martin's Press, p.34–39
- ^ a b Reed 2009, p. 12.
- ^ Weitzman, H. (2006, September 9). "'Ethical-coffee' workers paid below legal minimum." Financial Times
- ^ a b Valkila 2009, p. 3023.
- ^ Utting 2009, p. 141.
- ^ e.g. Murray, D., Raynolds, L., & Taylor, P. (2003). One cup at a time: Poverty alleviation and Fair Trade coffee in Latin America. Colorado State University
- Luetchford P (2006). "Brokering Fairtrade: relations between coffee producers and Alternative Trade Organizations - a view from Costa Rica" in D. Lewis and D. Mosse (eds), Development Brokers and Translators: the Ethnography of Aid and Agencies, Kumarian Press, Bloomfield
- CT Ronchi, L (2002a). The Impact of Fairtrade on Producers and their Organisations. A Case Study with COOCAFE in Costa Rica
- ^ Valkila 2009, p. 3024.
- ^ a b c Carimentrand, A.; Ballet, J. (2010). "When Fair Trade increases unfairness: The case of quinoa from Bolivia" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-03-28. Retrieved 2011-08-05.
- ^ Working paper FREE-Cahier FREE n°5-2010
- ^ a b c Doppler, F.; Cabañas, A.A.G. (June 2006). "Comercio justo: ventajas y sinsabores para los productores" [Fair Trade: Benefits and Drawbacks for Producers]. Puente @ Europa (in Spanish). IV (2): 53–56.
- ^ a b c Booth, Philip (20 February 2009). "Don't bully the faithful into buying Fairtrade". The Catholic Herald.
- ^ Boersma, F. (2009). "The urgency and necessity of a different type of market: the perspective of producers organized within the Fair Trade market" Journal of Business Ethics 86:51-61
- Boersma, F. V. (2002). "Poverty Alleviation through Participation in Fair Trade Coffee Networks: The Case of UCIRI, Oaxaca, Mexico"
- Audebrand, L., & Pauchant, T. (2009). "Can the Fair Trade Movement enrich Traditional Business Ethics? An Historical Study of its founders in Mexico" Journal of Business Ethics 87:343-353
- Gendron, C., V., B., & Rance, A. (2009). "The institutionalization of Fair Trade: more than just a degraded form of social action" Journal of Business Ethics 86:63-79
- McMurtry, J. (2009). "Ethical Value-Added: Fair Trade and the Case of Cafe Fenenino" Journal of Business Ethics 86:27-49.
- ^ Reed 2009.
- ^ Booth, P. (2008). The Economics of Fairtrade: a Christian perspective Archived 2009-09-06 at the Wayback Machine. London: Institute of Economic Affairs
- ^ Smith, Sally; et al. (2004). Ethical Trade in African Horticulture: Gender, Rights and Participation (PDF). Institute of Development Studies. ISBN 1-85864-833-5.
- ^ Julie Guthman (2007). "The Polanyian Way? Voluntary Food Labels as Neoliberal Governance". Antipode. 39 (3): 456–478. Bibcode:2007Antip..39..456G. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8330.2007.00535.x.
- ^ Davies, I.A. and A Crane, "Andrew Crane Ethical Decision Making in Fair Trade Companies", Journal of Business Ethics 45: 79–92, 2003. p. 84
- ^ Moberg, M (2005). "Fairtrade and Eastern Caribbean Banana Farmers: Rhetoric and Reality in the Anti-Globalization Movement". Human Organization. 64: 4–16. doi:10.17730/humo.64.1.j8ad5ffqqktq102g.;
- Cited in Nelson and Pound (2009) p 10
- Fraser (2009) cited in Griffiths, P (2012). "Ethical Objections to Fairtrade". Journal of Business Ethics. 105 (3): 357–373. doi:10.1007/s10551-011-0972-0. S2CID 153463544.
- ^ Hamel, I. (2006). "Fairtrade Firm Accused of Foul Play". Swiss Info. Archived from the original on 2013-08-21. Retrieved 2009-12-23.
- ^ Weitzman, H. (2006, August 9). "'Fair' coffee workers paid below minimum wage." Financial Times
- Weitzman, H. (2006, September 9). "'Ethical-coffee' workers paid below legal minimum." Financial Times
- ^ Boris, Jean-Pierre. (2005). Commerce inéquitable. Hachette Littératures. Paris.
- ^ Jacquiau, Christian (2006), Les Coulisees du Commerce Équitable [The columns of the equitable commerce] (in French), Paris: Mille et Une Nuits.
- ^ Catherine S. Dolan (2008), Research in Economic Anthropology, "Arbitrating risk through moral values: the case of Kenyan fairtrade", volume 28, pp. 271–296
- ^ Hayes, Mark (2008). "Fighting the Tide: Alternative trade organizations in the era of global free trade - A comment". World Development. 36 (12): 2953–2961. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00017-7.
- ^ LeClair, M. S. (2002). "Fighting the tide: alternative trade organizations in the era of global free trade". World Development. 30 (6): 949–958. doi:10.1016/s0305-750x(02)00017-7.
Bibliography
edit- Berndt, C.E. (2007), Is Fair Trade in coffee production fair and useful? Evidence from Costa Rica and Guatemala and implications for policy, Mercatus 65 Policy Series, Policy Comment, vol. 11, Washington, DC: Mercatus Centre, George Mason University.
- Kilian, B.; Jones, C.; Pratt, L.; Villalobos, A. (2006), "Is Sustainable Agriculture a Viable Strategy to Improve Farm Income in Central America? A Case Study on Coffee", Journal of Business Research, 59 (3): 322–330, doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2005.09.015.
- Kohler, P. (2006), The economics of Fair Trade: for whose benefit? An investigation into the limits of Fair Trade as a development tool and the risk of clean-washing, HEI Working Papers, vol. 6, Geneva: Economics Section, Graduate Institute of International Studies, October.
- Mohan, S. (2010), Fair Trade Without the Froth – a dispassionate economic analysis of 'Fair Trade', London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
- Valkila, J. (2009). "Fair Trade organic coffee production in Nicaragua – Sustainable development or a poverty trap?". Ecological Economics. 68 (12): 3018–3025. Bibcode:2009EcoEc..68.3018V. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.07.002.
- Utting, K. (2009). "Assessing the impact of Fair Trade Coffee: Towards an Integrative Framework". Journal of Business Ethics. 86: 127–149. doi:10.1007/s10551-008-9761-9. S2CID 154359304.
- Valkila, J.; Haaparanta, P.; Niemi, N. (2010). "Empowering Coffee Traders? The Coffee Value Chain from Nicaraguan Fair Trade Farmers to Finnish Consumers". Journal of Business Ethics. 97 (2): 257–270. doi:10.1007/s10551-010-0508-z. S2CID 146802807.